Preface to the English Edition |
9 | ||||
| |||||
|
| ||||
|
Present state of theory. |
14 | |||
|
| ||||
|
A general survey of the mode of organisation of present-day |
| |||
|
The commodity character of part of the production of the state |
| |||
|
Statisation, socialisation and taking over of the means of |
| |||
|
The social implications of state ownership. |
43 | |||
|
The more or less social nature of the productive forces. |
48 | |||
The production-relations within the state sector of the socialist |
| ||||
|
(a) |
Planned obligations to buy and sell. |
56 | ||
| |||||
|
|
Centralised economic management of certain branches of |
| ||
Economic subject and juridical subject. |
71 | ||||
|
(a) |
Determining the economic subjects. |
72 | ||
|
Internal structuring of economic subjects and working |
| |||
(b) |
Contractual relations. |
86 | |||
|
Contracts for buying and selling. |
86 | |||
The nature of the decisions to be taken by the different |
| ||||
Some problems of planning connected with the existence of eco- |
| ||||
|
(a) |
The role played by economic subjects in the drawing up of |
| ||
|
Procedures for consultation and participation. |
95 | |||
(b) |
Some contradictions or weaknesses in the present practice |
| |||
(c) |
The degree of exactness and the more or less obligatory |
| |||
|
Investments without security. |
101 | |||
(d) |
Methods used by the planning organs to lay down produc- |
| |||
(e) |
Methods of crrying out the plans. |
105 | |||
107 |
page 8 [blank]
Preface to the English Edition
In fact I sought, on the one hand, to define more precisely the nature of economic calculation, so as to bring out more clearly the point that what is usually meant by this term is in reality only a monetary calculation, of limited significance; and, on the other, to elucidate the nature of the social relations which make possible a monetary calculation of this sort.[1] At the same time, in a discussion with Paul Sweezy, I gave greater precision to my thinking about the problems of the transition to socialism and about the existence of a struggle between a socialist tendency and a capitalist tendency within the social formations in transition.[2]
Subsequently, I have undertaken a fresh critical evaluation of the economic, social and political changes that the U.S.S.R. has experienced since the revolution of 1917,[3] with a view to defining the limitations of these changes and the nature of the modifications undergone by the changes themselves in the course of time, as a result of class struggles. Thereby I have sought to identify more exactly the social foundations of present-day Soviet policy and its increasing subordination to the interests of a privileged minority which has de facto control of the means of production. Furthermore, the experience of the Chinese Revolution, and especially the lessons of the Cultural Revolution has led me to give greater emphasis to changes in the superstructure of society as a condition for progress towards socialism, and to stress that only a certain type of development of the productive forces can ensure genuinely socialist planning.[4] These different concrete analyses have consequently caused me to define more precisely and correct a number of my theoretical concepts. In view of all this, the following pages need to be read today not without taking account of the critical developments that I have mentioned.
CHARLES BETTELHEIM
Paris, February, 1974.
page 10
NOTES TO PREFACE
1
Cf. Charles Bettelheim, Calcul économique et formes de propriété, Paris, Maspero, 1970. To be published in U.K. by Routledge and Kegan Paul and in the U.S.A. by Monthly Review Press. [Transcriber's Note: See Economic Calculation and Forms of Property. -- DJR]
2
Cf. Paul Sweezy and Charles Bettelheim, On the Transition to Socialism, New York, Monthly Review Press, 1971 (122 pp.).
3
This investigation has resulted in the publication of a work entitled Les Luttes de Classes en URSS. The first volume, covering the period 1917-23, was published jointly, in 1974, by Maspero and Editions du Seuil. [Transcriber's Note: See Class Struggles in the USSR, First Period: 1917-1923 and then Class Struggles in the USSR, Second Period: 1923-1930. -- DJR]
4
Cf. Charles Bettelheim, Révolution culturelle et organisation industrielle en Chine, Paris, Maspero, I973.
TRANSLATOR'S NOTE
Since this book was translated and set in type ready for press, some books which are referred to in the original French editions have appeared in English. These are:
Charles Bettelheim, Cultural Revolution and Industrial Organisation in China,
London, 1974.
L. Althusser, E. Balibar, R. Establet, Reading 'Capital ', London, 1970.
N. I. Bukharin, The Economy of the Transition Period, New York, 1971.
K. Marx, Contribution to the Critique of Political Economy, London, 1971.
L. Althusser, For Marx, London, 1970.
K. Marx, Grundrisse, London, I973.
prepared, dealing with "the structures of transitional economies" (this tide is probably not definitive).[1]
It is worth stressing at the outset that the critical analyses demanded by the realities described below, and the concepts by means of which I have endeavoured to grasp these realities, cannot be restricted merely to the economic plane of the various social formations, but must also deal with the political and ideological planes and with the relations between these two and between them both and the economy. A way of proceeding such as this must, moreover, lead to critical analysis of certain generalisations that have been made at certain moments, on the basis of some aspect or other of Soviet economic reality or Soviet economic policy; for instance, some generalisations of the arguments put forward by Lenin in favour of the New Economic Policy.
What will be found here is thus merely the beginning of such an approach. Except in Chapter 6, the reader will find here no analyses dealing with economic calculation, and more especially with economic calculation on the scale of society. These analyses will not be made public until after critical consideration of the structures of economies in transition between capitalism and socialism. Nor will any analyses dealing with the People's Republic of China be found here; such an analysis has already been offered in another work -- a book containing contributions by other economists who also take part in the work of the Centre d'Études de Planification Socialiste (Centre for Study of Socialist Planning) and which appeared in the Economie et Socialisme series.[2]
These papers thus constitute only a first collection of thoughts aroused by the progress and difficulties of planning, and the political and ideological developments experienced by the socialist countries. These thoughts are put forward for discussion, which is indispensable if research and analysis are to be usefully carried on, so that, by an examination of the current phases of development, theoretical lessons and practical results may be drawn from them.
CHARLES BETTELHEIM
(August 1967)
NOTES TO FOREWORD
1
Now published as Les Luttes de Classes en URSS, Vol. I, 1917-23, Paris, Senil/Maspero, 1974.
2
Ch. Bettelheim, J. Charrière, H. Marchisio, La Construction du socialisme en Chine (Building Socialism in China), series Economie et Socialisme, Paris, Maspero, 1965. Reissued in the Petite Collection Maspero, March 1968.
I: The problematic of the
economy of transition
Empirically, this transition, or rather these transitions, appear to us in two forms.
In doing this, I shall start from a text which relates directly to our problems, namely, Louis Althusser's Sur la "moyenne idéale " et les formes de transition (On the "ideal average" and the forms of transition).[1] Here Althusser formulates some propositions which are of the greatest importance for our subject. I will set them out in the order that seems to me to be significant from the point of view of the problem with which we are concerned, an order which is a little different from that in which Althusser presents them:
First proposition
Althusser recalls that, in Capital, Marx sets himself the task of studying the "concept of the specific difference of the capitalist mode of production" and that he is able to do this only "on condition that he studies at the same time the other modes of production, as types of specific unity of Verbindung (i.e. of combination, C.B.) between the factors of production, and also the relations between the different modes of production in the process of constituting modes of production."[2]
Second proposition
Althusser further stresses that Marx's passages on primitive accumulation of capital form at least the materials, if not already the outline, of the theory of the process whereby the capitalist mode of production is consti-
page 15
tuted, that is to say, of the forms of transition from the feudal mode of production to the capitalist mode of production. This proposition evidently means, among other things, that these passages in Marx (together with those dealing with pre-capitalist modes of production) give us the outline of a theory (of transition ), but not yet -- since this was not the main purpose of Marx's scientific work -- the theory itself.
This situation of the theory is illuminated by Etienne Balibar's contribution to the same volume.[3]
Third proposition
This third proposition is closely linked with the first two.
Marx's theoretical object is the capitalist mode of production in its Kerngestalt (i.e., in its "nuclear structure" or "inner structure", C.B.) and the determinations of this Kerngestalt. This means that what Marx is studying is not, for example, capitalist England, which he often takes as an illustration, but an ideal object, defined in terms of cognition, in the abstraction of a concept. This is what Marx is saying when he writes that the "specific character" of the capitalist system "is revealed in all its inner essence".[4]
It is this specific difference that is Marx's theoretical object. This is why the capitalist mode of production he studies is a mode of production with two classes, differing from what we see in the English "illustration", or any other such "illustration" we might find, in which there are actually a much larger number of classes. The specific difference studied by Marx is thus not an empirical average but the concept of the capitalist mode of production, which constitutes that which is essential to it.
Fourth proposition
There is thus a "gap" between the capitalist mode of production in the reality of its concept and the actual economic system of British capitalism, for example. This "gap" constitutes what Althusser calls a "real residue",[5] an "impurity"[6] or, as he also says, what one may "provisionally call a survival" in the midst of the capitalist mode of production which is dominant in Great Britain.[6]
Fifth proposition
This fifth proposition is very directly concerned with our subject of study.
"This alleged 'impurity' is an object belonging to the sphere of the theory of modes of production: in particular, the theory of the transition from one mode of production to another, which merges with the theory of the process whereby a certain mode of production is formed. . . ."[6]
I should now like to offer some observations concerning the content of the fourth and fifth of these propositions:
(1) While it seems to me correct to say that the alleged "impurities", "survivals", etc., form an object belonging to the sphere of the theory of modes of production, I do not think that they can be the specific object of the theory of the transition from one mode of production to another. In fact, these "impurities" are always present in reality. They therefore cannot be considered as the peculiarity of a stage of transition, or otherwise we should have to say that the real economic world is always made up of economies in
page 16
transition, and consequently the concept of "economy of transition" would be deprived of any specific meaning.
If we wish to give the term "economy of transition" a specific meaning -- and this seems to me to be essential -- we must ask ourselves what these "residues" are that we find so difficult to describe, since we refer to them by means of all sorts of metaphors, like "impurities", "survivals", and so on, which is a sign that there is as yet no scientific concept with which to think these objects. Above all, we must, in particular, ask ourselves the following question: is it not rather a specific form of coexistence, or simultaneous presence and interaction of several modes of production, that characterises an economy of transition? And this leads to another question: do not these specific forms of coexistence and interaction of several modes of production constitute specific modes of production?
It is not necessary to work out forthwith the scientific concepts demanded by this way of seeing the problem, but only to offer some considerations which may perhaps help us to find a road that will lead to the establishment of these concepts. This leads me to make a second observation.
(2) What we will for the moment call "survivals" (an expression which makes one think of some legacy from a past which history has not had the time to wipe out) represent, in fact, the products of the structures in which these alleged "impurities" are not "survivals", because they are not alien to the real structures in which they exist. On the contrary, they are the result of the totality of the relations which make up these structures, that is to say, of the particular level of development of the productive forces, of the unevennesses of development which characterise these forces, and of, the relations of production linked with these unevennesses of development. If we think of these "impurities" as being "survivals" this is because we have not grasped thoroughly enough the interconnexions of the structures that produce them.
When, indeed, we set about studying an actual economy -- independently of the very idea of transition -- we have to think of this economy as a complex structure which is "structured in dominance ". We mentally grasp a structure like this as a specific combination of several modes of production of which one is dominant. It is this dominant mode of production that permeates the entire system and modifies the conditions in which the subordinate modes of production function and develop.
In other words, by virtue of their very subordination, these "modes of production" are different from what they are in their "purity". Marx speaks in this connexion of the "etiolation" of these modes of production.
What is true, however, of the subordinate modes of production is reciprocally true of the dominant mode of production, the features of which are also to some extent modified by the mere fact of its "dominant" role.
Finally, each of these complex structures constitutes not a simple juxtaposition of modes of production, but a complex structure which is unique, endowed with its own structural causality; At the same time, this unique
page 17
structure is subject, in general, to the dominance of a specific structure which corresponds to that of a given mode of production; for example, the capitalist mode of production. This is why it is that while, in a complex structure of this type, like nineteenth-century France, say, we find numerous structural elements belonging to modes of production other than the dominant mode, we are nevertheless justified in saying that this structure corresponds to that of a capitalist economy.
If the simultaneous presence and interaction of several modes of production is a feature of any actual economic structure whatsoever, then it is, of course, a feature of an economy in transition; but an additional element enters in here, namely, the mode of dominance and the methods of eliminating the non-dominant structures. This is one of the problems we shall have to examine.
I should like to illustrate the observation I have just put forward by taking the example of the situation in the Soviet Union in 1918 and in 1921.
In his report on the tax in kind, dated 9 April, 1921, Lenin said:
Under these conditions, even a certain development of capitalism, whether in the form of concessions to foreign capital, limited in scope and strictly regulated, or in that of a certain growth of internal capitalism, is incapable of changing the predominant orientation, owing to the working-class nature of the state and of the latter's grasp of what Lenin calls the "commanding heights of the economy".
I now return to the problems set by the analysis of any complex economic structure. In order to analyse such a structure, and especially in order to foresee how it will develop, we can apply the knowledge available to us concerning the way each of these "elementary structures" functions and develops. We must appreciate, however, that this method is only approximative. Its weakness is that it treats as independent modes of production elementary structures which possess no "autonomous" existence except in the idea that we form of them as distinct modes of production, that is, as modes of production which, in their very concepts, are pure structures. This is why the conclusions we can draw from such proceedings are still only approximate. Recognition of the divergences between these conclusions and reality must in the end lead to the conceptual construction of a
page 18
complex structure, structured in dominance, the structural causality of which correspond better to that of the actual economic system.
To this I should like to add that the "mixed" character of the actual structures and systems is not merely an "internal" feature of the various national economies but is also, and to an even greater extent, a feature characteristic of the world economy. For the development of the productive forces in every country is to some extent conditioned by world production-relations. This can be seen especially in the countries dominated by imperialism but it is also true in the dominating countries. This therefore means that the world economy itself is a complex structure of complex structures. Now, the world economy is the ultimate economic reality. It is in the world economy that are "combined" (in several dimensions) the most diverse modes and systems of production and the various national economies which form parts of this complex totality.
Thus, when we study the working of a particular national economy in which a certain mode of production seems to be "dominant" -- for example, the economy of some country in Latin America in which large-scale landownership is dominant on the spot -- we ought not, if we want to arrive at meaningful conclusions, consider this economy otherwise than in its mode of relations with the modes of production which are dominant on the world scale ; because we cannot understand this national economy if we do not grasp that it is a part of world production-relations. It is thus as an integrated structure, for example, as a structure dominated by the American economy, that the specificity of development of this economy can be understood.
Similarly, the transformations of structures and the different stages of transition that a national economy can undergo cannot be analysed in a valid way except by putting these transformations back into the world structural totality. In this way we can understand how it is that the stages of transition of each economy that carries out its socialist revolution can be qualitatively different from the "apparently analogous" stages passed through by the countries which have preceded it on the same road. This is so not merely for reasons internal to each economy, that is, because of the particular level of development of its productive forces and the unevennesses of this level of development, the class characteristics peculiar to this economy, and so on, but also because the world totality has itself been transformed. From this standpoint, the October Revolution marks the beginning of a new age, not only for the Russian economy but also for the world economy, the structure of which was profoundly transformed.
This leads me to formulate the following proposition: with the dividing up of the world by imperialism, a world economic system was established. The break-up of the unity of this system began with the October Revolution. Since then, world economy has entered a period of transition. The characteristics of this transition, its specific phases, need to be studied as an objective phenomenon with both national and international aspects. Such a study requires the elaboration of specific concepts. For the moment, we possess only practical concepts, and very poor ones at that, such as "co-
page 19
existence on the world scale" or "the world struggle between the two systems". Such concepts merely point to the existence of a problem, namely, that of the forms and phases of transition on the world scale; they do not as yet enable us to set this problem on the scientific plane. What constitutes the difficulty of the problem is not merely its size or its novelty, it is also the specificity of this world transition which implies political and ideological transformations at the level of the different states, for these are the transformations that, within each state, alter the dominance of a mode of production. These, for example, are what have brought it about that, in the course of a few months, the economy of Cuba ceased to be dominated by American capital and became integrated into the world socialist economy and has taken the road towards the building of socialism. The immediately national character of such transformations often makes us lose sight of the international nature of the process of transition.
After making these general observations, I should like to dwell upon some points of terminology, for through an effort to clarify terminology we may be able to make our way to a more rigorous formulation of the concepts.
The economy of the transition period is thus the economy of the period directly after a break, and this is why the theory of the transition is not a theory of origins but a theory of beginnings. In the strict sense of the word it is the theory of the beginnings of a new mode of production. One of its objects consists of the initial stage, or rather of the problems of the period of initial instability, of the period preceding what Marx calls the "social stability" of the mode of production.[9]
The initial stage is that in which the fate of the new social formation has not bet been sealed, or in which this fate is still uncertain. In both cases this stage corresponds to the "morning after" a break with a mode of production that was previously dominant, or to a serious shock to the former domination (the case of the period immediately following "de-colonisation" in a formerly colonial country). This "morning after" may, of course, extend in some cases over a number of years.
However, the problems of the economy of transition, as I propose to deal with them here, go beyond this phase of initial instability. They concern, as I have said, not merely the initial stage, as the first stage of the transition period, but the whole of the transition period as the first phase of a period of history. For example, in the case of the Soviet Union, I shall interest myself both in the period immediately following the October Revolution and in the present period.
What, then, constitutes the "transition phase " (in the sense of the phase of transition between capitalism and socialism, for example) is no longer the fact of instability or the absence of domination, but the fact of a still
page 23
relatively great lack of conformity between the essentials of the new social relations which are henceforth dominant and the productive forces, a state of affairs which also means a certain type of contradiction between the form of property and the real mode of appropriation. Under these conditions, the new social relations do not yet dominate by their own strength; in other words, the conditions for expanded reproduction of these social relations are not yet given.[10]
When such a situation of lack of conformity between the new social relations and the productive forces exists, the dominance of the new social relations can be ensured only through mediations, for example, in the case of the economy in transition to socialism, by having recourse to those two extreme types of mediation, use of the market (as in the example of the N.E.P.), or administrative centralisation (as in the example of the first Five-Year Plans). These mediations testify to the still very great depth of the internal contradictions.
The latter can only be resolved through a development of the productive forces which will bring about conformity between the new social relations and the productive forces themselves: in the case of the socialist economy, this development must lead to an integration and interdependence of the productive forces far-reaching enough for the mechanism of the market and the mechanism of administrative centralisation to be alike discarded and replaced by a co-ordinated management of the economy through original mechanisms, at the centre of which there will be a planning center of a new type.
The above observations call for additional terminological definitions. It seems right to reserve the term "phase " to indicate the two great moments in the development of a social formation, namely:
(1) that of its beginnings, i.e., the transition phase in the strict sense which is also that of a specific non-correspondence between productive forces and production-relations (this is a point to which I shall come back): and,
(2) the phase of expanded reproduction of the production-structure, which can be subjected to a synchronic analysis and is marked by a dynamism of its own.
Each of these phases is distinguished by a specific interconnexion between the levels of the social formation and between their contradictions, and so by a certain type of uneven development of these contradictions. In the course of one and the same phase, that which at one moment is a principal contradiction becomes a secondary one, or else a secondary aspect of this contradiction becomes a principal aspect. These shifts in contradictions show the pace of development of the different stages of a given phase; they are marked by changes in relations between classes or between the different strata of the same class. It was thus that the Kronstadt revolt and the economic crisis preceding it indicated such a shift and compelled the Bolshevik Party to change its economic policy. Lenin wrote at that time:
page 24
Having arrived at this point, we find two kinds of problem coming up:
(1) Is there a typical way of dividing up the transition period into stages, with specific features? If so,
(2) what are the relations between these typical stages and the historical periods through which the economies of the socialist countries have passed?
These are the questions which we must try to answer.
III A fundamental feature of the transition period
Thus, whereas social production-relations bring about a formal dissociation between the worker and his means of production, the labour-process maintains their unity. Non-correspondence between social production-relations and
page 25
the labour-process is thus characteristic of the period of transition to capitalism.
This non-correspondence is abolished later on, through the industrial revolution, the development of which was made possible by the formal subjection of labour to capital. The industrial revolution, that is to say, the development of the productive forces which this change implies, breaks up the unity of the worker with his means of production. The latter cease to be individual and become collective. Thenceforth there is separation of the worker from his means of work on the plane of the work-process no less than on that of social production-relations. There thus comes about a correspondence, what Etienne Balibar calls an homology, between the two forms of appropriation. With large-scale industry, the subjection of labour to capital is no longer merely formal, it is real, as-Marx puts it.[13]
As we know, this homology has at the same time an underlying contradiction, namely, that which counterposes the private ownership of the means of production to the social character of the productive forces.
To return to the period of transition to capitalism, we see, then, that this is marked by a certain form of non-correspondence. The latter also finds expression as a chronological gap, between the formation of the different elements in the structure: capital as a "social relation" exists previous to and independent of the "real" subjection of the worker, that is, of the specific form of real appropriation which corresponds to the capitalist mode of production.[14]
The question we now have to answer is the following: is the period of transition to socialism also marked by non-correspondence and a "chronological gap", this gap being itself destined to be closed by the triumph of a new type of industrial revolution, that is, by the predominance of productive forces with characteristics corresponding to the new social-production relations?; and this predominance itself being made possible as a result of the prerequisite appearance of socialist production-relations, that is, as a result of a certain type of "chronological gap"?
I think this question can be answered, in the affirmative, by putting forward the following propositions, which, of course, need to be elaborated. It seems that the form of "non-correspondence" specific to the phase of transition to socialism is the following: the mode of property is formally -- so far as the chief means of production are concerned -- that of ownership by society as a whole, whereas the real mode of appropriation is still by limited groups of working people, since it is only at the level of these groups that real appropriation of nature takes place.[15]
The chronological gap peculiar to the mode of production of transition to socialism would thus also mean the constitution of a mode of formal appropriation "preceding" the corresponding mode of real appropriation.
The material basis of this non-correspondence thenceforth appears as being constituted by the nature of the productive forces that are set to work
page 26
within the framework of what is still called the socialist "enterprise", or "firm", that is, of "enterprises" or "firms" which have to be allowed a certain degree of autonomy precisely because they form the framework in which the real appropriation of nature takes place.
From now on, however, the development of the productive forces in certain branches, e.g., in the production of electricity and in the large-scale chemical industry (in the form of big combines) reveals the appearance of a mode of real appropriation which can still be dominated at the level of society as a whole. When this evolution is complete in essentials, that is, when these productive forces of a new type are the dominant productive forces, there will be a state of homology between the mode of appropriation and the mode of property, there will be coincidence between juridical power and effective capacity, and the transition phase will be over. It would seem that it can be said straightaway that this presupposes a very far-reaching development of automation, technical integration and remote control methods of management.
On the basis of the foregoing, we see that what marks the transition phase as a whole is not mainly the instability of the new social order, nor is it the absence of domination by the new production-relations, it is the fact that there is still a relatively large degree of non-correspondence between the new production-relations, henceforth dominant, and the nature of the essential productive forces.
The lower the local level of development of the productive forces in a given country, the higher the degree of non-concordance of which we speak. It was in this sense that Lenin wrote in 1921 that:
"The economic basis of socialism is not yet there ."[16]
A gap like this has important consequences as regards the articulation of the different levels of the social structure. This non-correspondence implies, in fact, a specific efficacity of the political level. So long as there is non-concordance between the new production-relations and the nature of the productive forces, the functioning of the economic system can be ensured only by specific mediations. For example, in the case of the economy in transition to socialism, recourse has to be had to such mediations as state capitalism, use of the market (as with the N.E.P.) and strong administrative centralisation (as in the first Five-Year Plans).
This seems to me very important in relation to the study of the political superstructures of the transition period, in particular the forms of democracy and the role of the administrative apparatus. This is precisely why Lenin insisted on the idea of the "economic foundations" for the "withering away of bureaucracy" and the problems of what he called "combating the evils of bureaucracy".[16]
I think that it is by starting from the idea of non-correspondence between the formal and the real modes of appropriation, and by taking into account the extent and the specific forms of this non-correspondence, that we have to proceed in tackling the problems that arise at the different stages of the economy in transition to socialism, and that we can try to construct a theory
page 27
of these stages. That will enable us to see that, depending on the countries concerned, that is, on the initial extent of the non-correspondence and the specific forms of this non-correspondence, this transition period can be longer or shorter, and, above all, can be marked by the playing of a radically different role, as between one country and another, by the bureaucratic apparatus, and so by different forms of socialist democracy.
On the economic plane, it is the extent and the specific forms of non-correspondence that must be taken into account in correctly setting the problems of the role played by the market and by money, of the role (now being so much discussed in the Soviet Union) of direct relations between socialist enterprises, of organisational forms in agriculture, of changes to be made in the actual mechanism of planning, and so on.
All these problems are both economic and political. Solving them calls into question the relations between classes or the relations between the different strata of one and the same class, the relations between the "top section" and the "lower ranks", and so on. . . .[17] In other words, it is a matter of bringing to light the contradictions engendered by a certain type of non-correspondence. Such contradictions, if not properly dealt with, may take on an antagonistic character, or from contradictions of the secondary order become principal contradictions. For example, if the problem of small-scale peasant production is not handled correctly, this may lead either to a setback in the productive forces of agriculture (which had occurred before the introduction of N.E.P.) or to such an increased role being played by the market that the development of socialist production relations may be seriously compromised (as has happened in Yugoslavia).
In concluding these observations regarding the period of transition to socialism, a point needs to be made about the dimensions and the nature of the break separating the phase of transition to socialism from the phase of socialism's further development. It is obvious that this break will be even greater than that separating the transition phase from the last phase of capitalism. We can see already that this break will mean the end of the separation between manual and mental work and between operative work and management, that is to say, the end of subdivisions which are still important within the working class itself.
After these observations regarding the transition to socialism, I should like to go quickly over some problems relating to economies which have emerged from the colonial period. Here it is important to raise the question of the specific nature of these economies in transition.
One of the specific features of this transition is that the principal aspect of their present situation is not a result of the internal development of their past economic structure, that is, of an internal evolution of their productive forces which caused them to evolve from one stage to another. On the contrary, the productive forces of these countries were generally in a stagnant condition. Further, their post-colonial situation is dominated by the breakdown of a political dependence. This breakdown opens the way to
page 28
new possibilities, through specific interventions from the political plane into the plane of production-structures.
Just as the encounter between these colonial societies and the Western capitalist societies belonged, according to Balibar's analysis, to the diachrony of these societies, because it brought about a transformation in their mode of production,[18] so the breakdown of their dependence tends to bring about (quickly or slowly) a transformation in their mode of production. As with any transition of this kind, we see a specific mode of intervention by the state, law and political force in the mode of production. The rapid development of state intervention, the promulgation of development plans, the nationalisation of productive enterprises and foreign trade, are examples of these numerous irruptions from above at the level of the economic structures. What marks off these interventions from the transition to socialism is that they do not emanate from a state machine that belongs to the working class, or to an alliance of classes led by the working class, but from a state machine that upholds and defends the privileges of the economically dominant classes; here, what plays the decisive role is the contradiction between the making of certain investments and certain outside interests, and not, directly, the contradictions within the given society.
I would further add that, where economies that have emerged from the colonial period are concerned we shall have to study essentially something that, though it looks to us like an initial stage, is perhaps only the last stage of the old mode of production, that is, a dissolution that should then lead on to a real transition; where the socialist economies are concerned, on the other hand, we shall have to study several stages of the transition period. This will be the case, in particular, with the Soviet economy, of which the on-going transition phase can already be subdivided into a certain number of specific stages, each with its own distinct social and economic, and therefore political, features.
Accordingly, what I propose to examine are essentially the problems of these two types of economy of transition which are characteristic of the world today:
(1) The problems of the economies which have carried through a socialist revolution, that is, in which the problems of building socialism are on the order of the day.
It is not, of course, my aim to examine all these problems. It would certainly be more fruitful to give priority to those among them regarding which there is reason to believe that they present us with the most fundamental questions of theory. Among these there is, in particular, the place of simple commodity production, and even of petty capitalist production, in the first stages of an economy evolving towards socialism. This is one of the questions that were raised very sharply at the time when the N.E.P. was formulated.
Another question is that of the forms of transition from simple commodity production to co-operation. Here we find, notably, the case of the
page 29
collectivisation of agriculture in the Soviet Union, but it is necessary also to examine other procedures for transforming agriculture, such as those that have been employed in China.
A further question is that of the forms of mediation needed in order to dominate effectively the contradictions that may arise from the non-correspondence between the modes of formal and real appropriation. We must investigate, especially, the progressive role that these contradictions may be capable of playing, that is, the way they can drive the productive forces forward, and the conditions that have to be fulfilled in order that this may actually occur.
The questions raised by the linkage of problems of planning and problems of managing the economy will also have to be looked into, particularly through the experience of Cuba and the discussions that have taken place there.
When these questions are gone into thoroughly, it becomes apparent that they are fundamentally theoretical in character, and it is this content that we must endeavour to bring out, by analysing recent historical processes and the theoretical reflexions already formulated regarding these processes.
(2) The problems of the post-colonial economies. Among the questions raised by the evolution of these countries I will mention that of the role and significance of state capitalism. There is reason, for instance, to analyse the specific differences between this state capitalism from that which is developing, on the basis of monopoly capitalism, in the big imperialist countries. There is reason, too, to consider the specific differences between the state capitalism of countries which, like India, are dominated by a powerful industrial bourgeoisie, and the state capitalism established in countries with productive forces that are very little developed or where only a very small-scale bourgeoisie, essentially peasant and mercantile in character, is to be found, as, for instance, in Mali or Cambodia.
Finally, it is essential to study the new structures of capitalism, for the twofold reason that the study of these structures is undoubtedly very instructive for our understanding of certain problems that confront the socialist economies themselves and that on the other hand, the recent evolution of capitalism entails far-reaching repercussions on the potential evolution of the post-colonial economies. Here there arises, especially, the problem referred to by the practical concept of "neo-colonialism".
These are, for the moment, the main themes I propose to deal with. I have others in mind, too, but I think it is better to begin working together on themes that have already been defined, before trying to define more precisely the themes which we shall tackle later, or the order in which these will be tackled.
|
|
page 30
NOTES TO CHAPTER I
1
L. Althusser, E. Balibar, R. Establet: Lire le Capital, Paris (Maspero),
1965, Vol.2, pp. 179-85. (Eng. edn: Reading Capital, New Left Books, 1970.)
[p. 14]
2
Ibid., Vol. 2, pp. 182-3.
[p. 14]
3
E. Balibar: Sur les concepts fondamentaux du matérialisme historique (On the basic concepts of historical materialism), in ibid., Vol. 2, pp. 187-332.
[p. 15]
4
Marx, Le Capital, Tome VI, p. 257. (Eng. version from Capital, III, F.L.P.H. edn., p. 239.)
[p. 15]
5
Althusser et al., op. cit., p. 182.
[p. 15]
6
Ibid., p. 183.
[p. 15]
7
V. I. Lenin, Oeuvres completes, 4th edn., Moscow, 1962, Vol. 32,
p. 313 (Eng. version from Collected Works, Vol. 32, pp. 295-6. [Transcriber's Note: See Lenin's "Report on the Tax in Kind". -- DJR]).
[p. 17]
8
Ibid., p. 314 (Eng. version, p. 296).
[p. 17]
9
Marx, op. cit., Tome VIII, p. 174 (Eng. version from Capital, III, F.L.P.H. edition, p. 774).
[p. 22]
10
It is necessary to consider also an opposite situation, in which the old social relations can no longer dominate by their own strength, because henceforth the productive forces overflow, in a sense, the production-relations within which they are supposed to be confined. This situation is that of imperialism in its last stage, compelled to have recourse either to violent measures of coercion or to rapid increase of unproductive expenditure (mainly war expenditure, but also any other form of expenditure aimed at diverting part of the accumulation fund from productive use). This point will have to be examined separately.
[p. 23]
11
Lenin, op. cit., Vol. 32, p. 347 (Eng. version, p. 327 [Transcriber's Note: See Lenin's "Plan of the Pamphlet The Tax in Kind ". -- DJR]).
[p. 23]
12
Marx, op. cit., Tome I, p. 303 (Capital, I, Eng. edn. of 1938, p. 297).
[p. 24]
13
Marx, op. cit., Tome I, p. 535 (Capital, I, Eng. edn. of 1938, p. 518).
[p. 25]
14
E. Balibar, op. cit., Vol. 2, pp. 228-9.
[p. 25]
15
These are points which I have endeavoured to analyse below, in Chapter 2, "The socio-economic framework and the organisation of social planning", and in Chapter 3, "Forms and methods of socialist planning and the level of development of the productive forces".
[p. 25]
16
Lenin, op. cit., Vol. 32, p. 346 (Eng. version, p. 325).
[p. 26]
17
Lenin, ibid.
[p. 27]
18
Balibar, op. cit., Vol. 2, p. 314.
[p. 28]
page 31
2:
The socio-economic frame-
work and the organisation of
social planning[1]
I A general survey of the mode of organisation of
present-day planned economies
Consequently, these units are not mere technical subdivisions of what might have been conceived as a "single state trust". This expression, "a single state trust", was, we know, used by Bukharin in his book The Economy of the Transition Period, in which he maintained that, in an 'organised social economy", there was no place for economic science, but only for direct administration of things. We know, too, that this view was not accepted by the other Soviet leaders: Lenin, in particular, regarded it as utopian and as expressing an "ultra-Left" attitude.[2]
In the practice of present-day planned economy, the units of production are not mere technical units, but economic subjects, which as such take decisions, and which have had to be accorded a margin of initiative and responsibility that makes of them also juridical subjects. These juridical subjects are, as such, sources of rights and obligations. They are subject not only to the obligations imposed on them by the plan but also to the obligations which they themselves undertake.
The products that pass from one economic unit to another are, in general,
page 32
not shared out by way of administrative orders, but mostly circulate by way of purchases and sales, which give rise to payments.
There is thus, in most cases, not a sharing-out of products but a circulation of commodities ; there is money and there are prices, that is to say (at least in appearance), there are commodity categories, which in turn mean a system of accounting in terms of prices, a system of calculation in money, and differentiated wages, together with a financial system and a system of credit, with a state banking network which can make fairly long-term loans.
This is the description one can give of all the planned economies at present in being, whether those in which the productive forces are most highly developed, as in the Soviet Union or in Czechoslovakia, or those in which agriculture still plays a big part, and where the productive forces are comparatively undeveloped, as in China or in the Democratic Republic of Vietnam.
This complex reality, this combination of socialist state property and social planning, on the one hand, with commodity categories (or at least the appearance of them), on the other, may seem to contradict some of the descriptions of socialist society given in advance by Marx or Engels.
II Some passages from Marx and Engels
I shall recall, in particular, that in the Critique of the Gotha Programme (written in 1875), Marx wrote, among other things:
page 33
just emerged from capitalist society. It is for this society, that is, for this economy of transition, that he foresees each worker receiving, instead of wages in money, "a certificate from society that he has furnished such and such an amount of labour (after deducting his labour for the common funds), and with this certificate he draws from the social stock of means of consumption as much as costs the same amount of labour." (Ibid., p. 23; Eng. trans., p. 20.)
According to this passage, there will be in socialist society, even at its beginning, neither commodities, nor value, nor money, nor, consequently, prices and wages. This is the same idea which Marx had already formulated in Capital and which about a year later Engels took up again in Anti-Dühring, especially when he wrote:
III The nature of the problems to be studied
If we accept that the present-day socialist economies, as they really are, correspond to objective demands imposed by the working and development of these social formations[4] and not to "distortions" of an "ideal model" (which Marx and Engels always refused to provide), we have to ask ourselves how to explain the contradiction which there at least seems to be between this reality and some of the analyses made by Marx and Engels.
It is all the more essential to do this because the good or bad working of the planned economy is obviously affected, in a decisive way, by the forms given to the organisation of this economy, and so by the role assigned to the production units, to exchange between these units, to money, prices, and so on.
On another plane, the role played by commodity categories in the planned economies of today is not without far-reaching influence on behaviour and attitudes, and, more generally, on the ideological superstructures. For this reason, too, one cannot omit to investigate the reasons why commodity categories have been retained, at least in appearance.
Furthermore, the frequent changes in organisation which take place in the various socialist countries (especially, in recent years, in the Soviet Union), the hesitations and fluctuations (towards a greater or lesser degree of centralism, or of autonomy allowed to the enterprises) which these changes reflect, make it plain that the final achievement of the best form of organisation, that is, the best adapted to the level of development and the nature of the present productive forces, as also to the requirements for building socialist society, cannot be regarded as having already been fully attained (though it is through such changes that these requirements make themselves felt).
page 34
The hesitations in the practical sphere themselves show that what is being gone through at present is a stage of research which involves a substantial element of trial and error. That does not mean, of course, that theoretical considerations play no part in current researches, but the hesitations in the field of practice show us that these theoretical considerations do not yet constitute a body of thought strongly structured enough to be capable of guiding with exactitude the search for the best forms of organisation.
We must therefore also look into the theoretical considerations which are generally accepted, and see to what extent we can carry a little further the analyses which underlie them.
This thought is closely linked with a thought about the structure of the plans and about the means of putting them into effect.
By "structure of the plans" I have in mind the order of the dimensions in which the aims of the plan are laid down (both physical and non-physical dimensions), the degree of detail into which the planners go in laying down these aims, and the nature of the plan-indicators that are made binding on each enterprise.
By "means of putting the plans into effect" I mean the respective parts played by administrative orders, economic calculation and the various instruments that are available for directing the economy. For the moment, of course, I shall deal with these different problems only in their most general aspect.
To begin with, I shall say a few words about the most obvious reasons for the apparent contradiction between the present mode of organisation and functioning of the planned economies and some of the formulations made by Marx and Engels, formulations which they always put forward with the greatest caution and which they always refused to offer as anticipations.
Among the most obvious reasons for the retention of commodity categories within the socialist economies of today we must mention the presence in these economies of several different forms of property.
IV The diversity of forms of property in the means of
production
We know that, in Economic Problems of Socialism in the USSR, Stalin put forward a refutation of the view according to which there is a contradiction between the existence of commodity production in the USSR and the passage we have quoted from Engels, in which the latter declares that "the seizure of the means of production by society puts an end to commodity production".
Stalin notes that, in this passage, Engels does not make clear whether what is involved is the seizure by society of all the means of production, and he rightly observes that, in another passage in Anti-Dühring, Engels speaks of society's taking possession of "all means of production". (Costes edn., Vol. III, p. 68: Eng. edn., p. 326.)
Stalin draws the conclusion that, for Engels, the disappearance of com-
page 35
modity production presupposed the expropriation of all the means of production in a country (which has not taken place either in the USSR or in any other socialist country). Stalin does not seem sure, moreover, that commodity production would really disappear even if all the means of production were nationalised, at least in countries where foreign trade continues to play a big part.
Indeed, we must take note that, after having remarked that it is only in Britain that, in his view, it would be possible, given the high degree of concentration of agricultural production, to nationalise all the means of production and so to eliminate commodity production, Stalin adds, immediately:
After putting this question, Stalin points out that Lenin answered it, in particular in two of his works, that on the tax in kind and that on co-operation.
This is true, even though, in these works, Lenin did not answer the question in exactly the same terms as Stalin.
Here I think it is necessary to insert a parenthesis.
In the summary given by Stalin (op. cit., p. 14) of Lenin's theses on co-operation and on the introduction of the tax in kind (Lenin's report to the 10th Congress of the R.C.P. (B), entitled "Report on the substitution of a tax in kind for the surplus-grain appropriation system"*, 15th March 1921, the collective farms are indeed put in the centre of the analysis. However:
(1) When Lenin defended the thesis of commodity exchange, he was obviously not thinking of the collective farms, which hardly existed at that time, but of the individual peasants, and in particular the middle peasants. He says so expressly when he writes: "We must try to satisfy the demands of the middle peasants", and when he adds that this satisfaction cannot be given without "a certain freedom of exchange" (Lenin, L'alliance de la classe ouvrière et de la paysannerie (The alliance between the working class
page 36
and the peasantry), Moscow, 1957, pp. 742-3) (Eng. version, Collected Works, 4th edn., Vol. 32, pp. 217-18.)
(2) When Lenin speaks of co-operation, he has in mind not only, or even mainly, producer co-operatives (i.e., collective farms) but also, and especially, trading co-operatives (for buying and selling). This emerges clearly from what he says about co-operative stores, and from his declaration that, in order to be a good co-operator one must be "a cultured trader". (Ibid., pp. 828 and 829: Eng. version, Collected Works, Vol. 33, p. 470.)[5]
Though the second of these observations is not of fundamental importance for the main subject of our present discussion, I think it is necessary to make it for at least two reasons:
a) Because, since the collectivisation of 1928-9, Lenin's idea of the development of co-operatives has been associated in a one-sided way with the idea of the development of collective farms, which was not Lenin's conception -- for him the development of co-operatives embraced all forms of co-operation -- and:
b) Because Lenin ascribed very great importance to co-operatives in the framework of the building of socialism. We know that he wrote: "And given social ownership of the means of production, given the class victory of the proletariat over the bourgeoisie, the system of civilised co-operators is the system of socialism." (Ibid., p. 830: Eng. version, Collected Works, Vol. 33, p. 471.)[5]
V The commodity categories within the state sector
1 The commodity character of part of the production of the state
sector
I have already mentioned that Stalin expressed doubt whether, in a country like Britain, where foreign trade plays a very important role, commodity production might not be retained, even if all the means of production were nationalised.
I will leave aside, for the moment, the problem set by the influence of foreign trade on the retention of commodity production. This is a problem of considerable theoretical importance, since, through it, the following question is being asked: does not the complete disappearance of commodity production presuppose also the achievement of socialism throughout the world, and real international planning?
For the moment it is the commodity character of the production of consumer goods that will occupy our attention.
Let me recall, first, that after having mentioned that objects for personal use are disposed of as commodities, Stalin goes on to say:
(1) First of all one ought to explain why consumer goods are sold for
page 38
money, and not distributed in exchange for labour-certificates, as Marx foresaw in his Critique of the Gotha Programme. So long as this is not explained, the problem is merely shifted elsewhere, not solved.
(2) Secondly, even if for the time being we accept the explanation given for the retention of commodity production by the fact that objects of personal consumption are sold, this does not seem to help us to understand why, within the state sector, the means of production are bought and sold and bear a price, etc.
Stalin perceived this difficulty, and formulated a second explanation.
2 The requirements of calculation
If calculations have to be made in commodity categories, then this must surely be because these categories possess a certain reality. What, indeed, would be the use of calculations carried out with categories that did not express a certain reality?
This is the heart of the question, and it is not answered by merely remarking, as Stalin does, that the content of the commodity categories is not the same as under the framework of capitalism.
It is indeed obvious that these categories do not relate to the same social relations, but they exist nevertheless, they possess reality, they are not just a "pure form" of accountancy, and it is this fact that they exist that has to be explained.
All the more necessary is it to explain their existence because, on the one hand, this does not seem to have been foreseen by theory, and, on the other, the explanation given will be helpful, as regards principle, in dealing with these categories as the expression of real phenomena, with an objective existence (from which likewise follow objective requirements) and not as "conveniences for calculation" which could therefore be manipulated in an arbitrary fashion.
There is something even more important: discovery of the raison d'être of commodity categories in the planned economy of today is a necessary stage in the establishment of effective conditions for the disappearance of these
page 39
commodity categories at a later stage, the stage regarded as the ultimate aim towards which contemporary economic plans have the task of carrying the planned economies.
Before examining what seems to me to form the bases for the existence of commodity categories in the planned economies of today, including their presence within the state sector, I think it will be useful to recall briefly some of the conclusions that have been drawn, or which could be drawn, from the analyses in Stalin's Economic Problems. . . . I think it will also be of use to note certain thoughts that are to be found in this work and which may be helpful to us in formulating a reply to the question before us.
3 The conditions for the disappearance of commodity categories,
according to Stalin's "Economic Problems . . ."
These conditions are, he considers, a relatively higher rate of expansion of the production of means of production; such a cultural advancement of society as will secure for all its members an all-round development of their physical and mental abilities, and which will put an end to the present division of labour; and the gradual disappearance of collective-farm property,
page 40
which will be replaced by a form of public property that will make it possible, "by means of gradual transitions, to replace commodity circulation by a system of products-exchange, under which the central government, or some other social-economic centre, might control the whole product of social production in the interests of society". (Op. cit., p. 56: Eng. edn., p. 75.)
4 Discussion of the preceding theses
This leads us to raise the following questions:
If this is so, we can say that it is when, and because, society has become capable of consciously regulating its production by reference to its needs (that is, of expending social labour-power "consciously", as Marx puts it)[6] that the commodity categories will disappear, and not the other way round, with the disappearance of commodity categories enabling society to regulate production on the basis of needs.
By putting the problem in this way we are therefore led to say:
a) That the root of the retention of commodity production and commodity categories is the absence of a social-economic centre effectively capable of disposing of all the products, and strictly regulating production in relation to the needs of society;
b) that the absence of this centre is connected, in the first instance, with the existence of several forms of property;
c) that, beyond this diversity of forms of property (and underlying it), it is the present level of development of the productive forces, which is still inadequate, that prevents a social-economic centre from being able effectively to dispose, consciously, of all the products, and really to regulate production according to the needs of society.
Observation of the objective conditions of the functioning of the state sector in the countries with planned economies shows that, even in this sector, a single centre does not attain to such power to dispose and regulate,
page 42
and it is from this that follows the necessity for a certain autonomy of the enterprises, the need to endow these enterprises with certain powers of disposal, a certain freedom of manoeuvre, which in turn results in the rules of business accounting, the money economy within the state sector, the commodity categories, etc.
Having arrived at this point we must, however, raise two questions:
a) In the last formulation we have reached, are we not mistaking effect for cause? More concretely, is it not because the enterprises have been given certain powers that there is no social centre really capable of regulating production by needs?
b) Does not the preceding analysis amount to calling into question the view taken by Marx and Engels that, when society takes possession of an the means of production, commodity production will cease ?
These two questions are closely linked, and so the answers I am going to try and formulate will likewise be closely linked.
VI Statisation, socialisation and taking over of the means of
production by society
It seems to me that this question must be answered in the negative.
Of course there are conclusions to be drawn from this experience. But these conclusions can only be drawn if the tools appropriate to the analysis of this experience are used, that is to say, correctly worked-out concepts. It is precisely the confrontation of the practical experience of planning with ideas which have not always been defined with sufficient rigour[7] that should enable us to refine our concepts more thoroughly, and thereby to understand better both the experience itself and the true significance of certain analyses made by Marx and Engels.
In the argument which follows I shall not take the excessively long and pointlessly complicated line of presenting first an analysis of the experience of the planned economies and only then, on the basis of this analysis, formulating more rigorously the concepts enabling us to interpret this experience.
I shall confine myself to the second procedure, that is, I shall try to reformulate certain concepts more precisely and then interpret certain
page 43
passages on the basis of this reformulation: this is how I shall endeavour to take account of practical experience, i.e., through a concrete analysis which I shall not develop here.
Let us begin then, by re-reading certain passages in the light of experience, in order to try and clarify the concepts and establish a unified interpretation of them.
1 The social implications of state ownership
b) Engels has also shown that when "the proletariat seizes the state power", it "transforms the means of production in the first instance into state property", and he adds (ibid., pp.46-7: Eng. edn., pp. 308-9): "The first act in which the state really comes forward as the representative of society as a whole -- the taking possession of the means of production in the name of society (my emphasis, C.B.) -- is at the same time its last independent act as a state. The interference of the state power in social relations becomes superfluous in one sphere after another, and then ceases of itself. The government of persons is replaced by the administration of things, and the direction of the processes of production. The state is not abolished, it withers away ."
If we think about these passages and try to clarify them in the light of the lessons of social praxis, we see that what Engels is saying is that when the state controlled by the proletariat "takes possession of the means of production", it does this "in the name of society", which is not the same thing as society's taking possession of them. It is later, in proportion as the state withers away and the administration of things replaces the government of persons, that there really occurs the taking possession of the means of production by society, which administers itself.
If we read the passage from Engels in this way we can appreciate that
page 44
commodity production does not "cease" abruptly, as might be suggested by the interpretation according to which taking possession by the state is equivalent to taking possession by society, but that it withers away as the process of taking possession by society advances, since this taking possession is a phenomenon that is realised in the course of a period of history, simultaneously with the withering away of the state.
When we put the problem in these terms, we see that ownership of the means of production by the proletarian state is not yet direct taking possession by society, but the stage that leads to this, on condition that other stages follow (whence the importance, for an entire period of history, of the dictatorship of the proletariat, in order to ensure that the state shall really act in the interests of the working people, and that the retention of the commodity categories, money, and so on, shall not bring about the rebirth, in new forms, of the exploitation of man by man).
This leads us to make a distinction between statisation (even by a workers' state) and socialisation. This is the point I shall now consider.
2 Statisation, socialisation, domination of the productive
forces by society
page 45
State ownership is a necessary condition for socialisation on the plane of the state (which is not yet socialisation directly on the plane of society), but it is not by itself a sufficient condition. In order that there may be socialisation on the plane of the state, the latter must have the capacity to dispose effectively and efficiently of the means of production and their products. Without this capacity, we have nationalisation without socialisation. Such a capacity results from an historical development, it is connected with the actual development of the productive forces (which include men themselves, and the level of their knowledge) and with the correlative transformation of production-relations.
I shall have to come back later to various aspects of the problem of the greater or lesser correspondence between juridical authority to dispose of certain means of production and effective capacity to dispose of these means of production. We know that what matters, in the last resort, is concrete capacity and not abstract "authority".
It is quite obvious that, on the basis of one and the same state ownership of the means of production (i.e., on the basis of the same juridical form), many degrees of concrete capacity to set these means of production to work are possible. It is therefore only if there is a sufficient level of capacity that there is real domination by society, or by the state acting in the name of society, over the means of production, and thus effective taking possession by society. Only when the taking possession by society of which Engels speaks attains a sufficient degree and level can society allot social labour in a conscious way, and the commodity categories disappear.
The building of socialist society is thus an historical process during which planning begins by being social direction of the productive forces (through a -- more or less complete -- effective socialisation of these forces), and becomes social domination of them (which leads to the complete disappearance of commodity production).
The fact, explicitly recognised by Lenin, that statisation does not automatically coincide with socialisation, in the sense of effective "social direction" of the statised means of production (and, so, a fortiori, in the sense of
page 46
social domination of these means of production) is fully confirmed by the difficulties encountered in putting plans into application even within the state sectors of the socialist economies of today. The successes achieved in this effective planning, and the difficulties encountered, show precisely that the objective conditions for real social domination over the forces of production are only in the process of coming into being, and this is why it is necessary to allow a relative freedom of manoeuvre either to the production units of the state sector or to certain "economic groups" which can be called economic subjects.
It must be emphasised at this point that the non-coincidence between nationalisation and effective social direction stands out very clearly when one considers the nationalisation of the land from the standpoint of its consequences in respect of the social direction of the productive forces of agriculture.
In the Soviet Union, for example, the land was nationalised at the time of the October Revolution, but exploitation of the land (that is, the practical setting to work of the productive forces of agriculture) was for a long time after that event mainly undertaken by individual peasants.[8]
Twelve years after the October Revolution (on the morrow of the collectivisation carried out during the First Five-Year Plan), the exploitation of the greater part of the land was the responsibility of the collective farms, that is, not of the state or of organs directly dependent on the state, but of groups of working peasants.
The efforts of the Soviet state to direct the productive forces of agriculture have taken, successively or simultaneously, a variety of forms: production-plans of the collective farms, ratified by the state organs, directing role of the Machine and Tractor Stations, plans for commercialisation of agricultural production, use of "economic levers" (i.e., especially, the price system). At present the state uses essentially indirect methods to direct collective-farm agriculture. I shall return to this point in a moment.
Furthermore, even today, the production realised on the peasants' individual holdings is only indirectly or very imperfectly the object of social direction, though the land of these individual holdings is also state property. If this is so, it is not, of course, because the production of the individual holdings is of slight economic interest -- on the contrary, the contribution made by these holdings to total consumption is far from negligible -- but because the very nature of the productive forces put to work on these holdings does not allow of effective and direct social direction of their use.
To a lesser extent (that is, with a greater possibility of social direction), this is also true of the productive forces of the collective farms: this is what accounts for the abandonment of attempts, never crowned with success, at direct planning of collective-farm production and the attempt to direct it indirectly, through plans for commercialisation and the combination of technical and administrative management (to which corresponded the creation, in March 1962 of collective-farm-and-state-farm production managements)[9] and the increasing use of "economic levers"
page 47
through the revision of the system of agricultural prices, carried out several times since 1953).
Thus we see that what, besides state ownership (which is the starting point and basis of real planning), is equally necessary for direct social direction of the productive forces is a sufficient development of these forces, resulting in their having a sufficiently social character. So long as this development is inadequate, state ownership may remain partly an empty juridical framework. As Marx puts it in the Critique of the Gotha Programme :
If this correspondence is ensured, the production-relations do not impede the development of the productive forces. If it is not ensured, if there is a contradiction between the production-relations and the character of the productive forces, the latter do not develop as fast as they technically could, they develop irregularly, through a succession of periods of slow development and other periods of more or less rapid development, and perhaps even periods of stagnation.
One of the essential problems of the development of the planned economy is to ensure the fullest possible correspondence between the production relations and the character of the productive forces. It is by way of this correspondence, consciously sought for, that the socialist state, which is master of the "commanding heights" of the economy -- that is to say, which has eliminated private ownership of the social means of production -- is able to ensure the overall direction of the productive forces, expanded reproduction on the scale desired, and preparation of the conditions for complete social domination of the productive forces, a domination which will be finally ensured by the disappearance of the commodity categories and of the state itself.
page 48
Treating the productive forces in accordance with their nature means, first, recognising the degree of actual socialisation of the various productive forces, and then adapting property-forms and production-relations (i.e., the forms taken by relations between the producers, individually and collectively) to the degree of socialisation, which is constantly increasing, of the productive forces. It thus signifies recognising certain objective requirements and conforming to them. Without conforming to them it is not possible to give social direction to the development and utilisation of the productive
The first requirement that has to be met if social planning is to be ensured, the most fundamental requirement of all, is that the state should take possession, in the name of society, of all the means of production and exchange which are really social in character.
The more or less social character of a production process and, therefore, of the means of production employed in it, is essentially linked with two types of evolution:
(1)The increasingly social origin of the means of production which are set to work in the given production-process;
(2) The increasingly social destination of the products which emerge from the given production-process.
By the "increasingly social origin" of the means of production set to work in a given production-process is meant the fact that these means of production come from an increasingly large number of branches of the economy. Thus, in the beginning, agriculture, for example, is more or less self-sufficient; that is, the number of means of production of extra-agricultural origin (or, at the level of the agricultural unit of exploitation, coming from outside this unit) which are employed is very limited. Increasingly, however, agricultural production comes to depend on means of more and more diverse origin: tools, machinery, fuel, electrical equipment, electric power, fertiliser, insecticides, herbicides, etc. The same is true in every branch of industry, starting with the extractive industries and going on to embrace the transformative industries, and in every unit of production.
The increasing socialisation of the productive forces is thus shown in the fact that every branch has recourse to means of production from an ever-greater variety of sources. This process is the other aspect of the increasing division of labour and the increasing specialisation of economic activities. It is this socialisation of labour that forms the objective basis for planning and renders it both possible and necessary, owing to the increasing interdependence of the various elementary processes of production.
We are now able to measure, more or less accurately, by means of certain coefficients, the degree of socialisation (from the standpoint just explained) of different branches of production in a number of countries.
For example, if we consider the use, direct and indirect, of industrial
page 49
products by agriculture, we see that for a value of gross production equivalent to 1,000 the consumption of industrial products by agriculture is 61 in Italy, 78.3 in France, 88.8 in the USSR, 89.9 in Britain and 108.7 in the USA.[10] In the case of very advanced agricultural units the industrial in-put coefficients would, of course, be very much higher.
These percentages are, naturally, affected by the comparative levels of industrial and agricultural prices; they are none the less significant, however.
More detailed analysis of the industries that contribute to agriculture's productive consumption also gives interesting results. It emerges that, for a gross production value of 1,000, American agriculture consumes 4.4 products of the engineering industry, while Soviet agriculture consumes 27.8; on the other hand, consumption of products of the chemical industry is 21.1 in the United States, and 7.7 in the Soviet Union, on the same basis.
By "increasingly social destination of the products" is meant the fact that the products arising from a production-process are destined, generally speaking, to be sold to an increasing number of users, either directly or indirectly. This phenomenon has various aspects:
A. Each branch of production works, either directly or indirectly, for an increasing number of other branches. This is merely another side of the increasing social division of labour. Thus, the chemical industry which, when it appeared as a distinct sphere of production, worked in the first place only for a small number of other industries, has progressively expanded the field in which its products are used. Today this field is practically universal. It ranges from agriculture through the extractive industries, to the metal-working industries (especially in the treatment of metals), etc. If we take indirect uses into account, we see that at the present time every branch of production is virtually working for every other branch, and consequently feels the impact of every fluctuation that may occur in any sector of the economy.
To illustrate the extent to which the products of one branch of industry are distributed through the others, it is possible to use other coefficients besides the foregoing.
For example, one may use for this purpose the coefficient of productive utilisation" (in the sense of intermediate consumption) of the products of the different branches. In terms of prices at the point of production, we find that 63.5 per cent of Soviet agricultural production is destined for intermediate consumption, as against 71.3 per cent of American, 54.6 per cent of Hungarian and 45.2 per cent of Yugoslav.
For the same purpose of discovering the degree of socialisation of production (in the sense of this word now being considered) we can examine the figures relating to the degree of utilisation by various industries of the products of each industry (see on this point the table on page 832 of the German translation of the article mentioned in note 10).
As Berri and Shvikov write in this article: "A comparison of the structures of production, using inter-sectoral balances, enables us to discover
page 50
important features in the production-structures of different countries, features which are determined above all by the degree of development of technique and of the social division of labour. . . ." (Ibid., pp. 832-3.)
B. The increasingly social destination of the products is also shown in another way, when we examine the size of the community served by a production-unit. With the advance of the productive forces this size usually (though not necessarily) grows larger. Thus, it may successively be local, micro-regional, regional, national or international.
The need for state ownership of certain means of production is all the greater because these means of production are used in activities (or in economic units) which are more thoroughly integrated in the social division of labour, either through the very nature of the means of production employed or through the destination of the products.
b) The degree of socialisation of the productive forces and the levels and forms of ownership of the means of production.
In all these cases, the concrete forms that must be assumed by the new
We thus come back to the problems we raised earlier, about the nature of the relations established between the producers, or the groups of producers (which constitutes the fundamental aspect of the production-relations),[11] and about the nature of the economic and juridical subjects within the socialist sector belonging to the state.
4 The production-relations within the state sector of the
socialist economy
Before analysing more closely the bearing of the facts mentioned above, and the objective conditions for them to disappear, we must throw light on the existence, in the socialist economies of today, of three categories of phenomena which seem, as it were, to presage or announce beforehand the ways in which economic subjects possessing a certain amount of autonomy will vanish from the scene.
a) Planned obligations to buy and to sell.
This latter practice is very widespread in the Soviet Union and in the socialist countries of Europe. Where it prevails, it reduces the part played by contracts between enterprises to that of executive instruments of a plan for allotting products, or that of giving concrete form to certain minor aspects of the obligations laid down by the plan.[12]
In reality, it seems to me, this practice can mean two opposite things:
(1) In some instances, this practice results from a situation of comparative shortage, i.e., of a poor adjustment between resources and needs.
In that sort of situation, the total amount of demand pressing upon current production, as expressed by the using enterprises (whether productive or trading enterprises matters little) at the given price-level, and given their financial resources and the tasks they have to carry out, would tend to exceed supply. When this is so, and if, for some reason or other, no change is made in any of the factors mentioned above (price-level, amount of financial resources, scope of tasks to be carried out), an administrative share-out is unavoidable. This sharing-out of the products by administrative methods may be provided for in the plan or it may be effected by administrative decisions which are distinct from the plan in the strict sense, though taken in pursuance of it.
Whatever the procedure followed, the application of an administrative share-out reduces to the minimum the "freedom of manoeuvre" of the production-units and also reduces to small importance the practical bearing of the contracts made between these units. Nevertheless, a situation like this, which itself results from a state of comparative shortage, cannot be seen as presaging the disappearance of economic subjects endowed with a certain degree of autonomy and the correlative disappearance of the commodity categories. This situation is not the consequence of an abundant and harmonious increase in the productive forces but, on the contrary, of a still weak and insufficiently harmonious development of these forces.
(2) In other instances, contrariwise, centralised sharing-out of certain
page 57
products does not reflect the inadequacy of the amount of these products available, but results from the fact that only one central authority is in a position to estimate how to ensure the best social utilisation of the products under consideration.
One can cite as examples of such cases the centralised allocation of investment resources and of certain capital goods, when this allocation can be done optimally only by taking into account a wide range of factors, such as the future pace of development of the various production-units (some of which may belong to an extremely wide variety of branches of production). Another example is that of the calculations required for the optimum spatial arrangement of the production-units to be set up. The part to be played by a central authority becomes decisive as soon as it is necessary to take into account factors which are beyond the economic "horizon" of each production-unit taken separately and which therefore cannot be included in economic calculations carried out at the level of one isolated unit.
When this is so, a situation really exists in which the commodity categories and the relative autonomy of the production-units have ceased (at least so far as the operations under consideration are concerned) to be adequate instruments for expressing social needs, even indirectly. In such a situation, the needs are, and can only be, grasped directly and expressed without recourse to commodity categories.
All the same, one may ask whether, in a case like this, recourse to the administrative share-out is really the most appropriate method of allotment, or whether it may not rather mean that practices dating from a situation of shortage are being applied to a different situation.
There are, in fact, other ways of effecting a centralised allotment besides the purely administrative way. These ways are less rigid than the latter and they are, moreover, often actually used. Without wishing to make too much of this aspect of the matter, I think it may be useful to note the following points:
A centralised allotment of certain means of production can be accomplished, for example, by setting up a central office for buying and selling all products of a certain kind. Centralised allotment by this method can be economic rather than administrative. Thus, the central office for buying and selling can be entrusted, under the plan, with:
(1) Conveying orders to the various production-units for the goods which the central office has to "allot", these orders being conveyed in accordance with the plan, as regards both specifications and delivery dates; while, on the other hand,
(2) The production-units which, under the plan, will have to use the products in question, send their orders for these products to the central office.
The central office can thus keep a clear running account of the actual allotment of the products for which it is responsible and, if necessary, can modify the priority in which the users will receive the goods they have ordered, so as to allow for the actual way the situation is evolving, and
page 58
especially for the real capacity of each particular user to instal a given piece of equipment at a given moment.
In this way the direct link that would otherwise be established between a particular supplier and a particular user can be broken. A direct link of this kind, though it offers great advantages in some cases (fixing of responsibility on definite persons, adaptation of the quality of the products to the users' requirements, etc.), may also offer serious inconveniences from the standpoint of social supervision of the allotment and use of a certain number of products. This type of direct link may, in particular, result in a user who should have been given priority having to put up with delays due to the fact that his supplier has made a quicker delivery to another user. Similarly, this type of direct link may result in a supplier honouring his contract by despatching equipment to a user who is, in practice, not in a position to instal this equipment forthwith.
The existence of central offices for buying and selling does not necessarily mean, of course, that these offices themselves have to take delivery of the actual products they allot: sometimes this may occur, but sometimes the offices may confine themselves, at whatever time they choose, and taking all the circumstances into account, to instructing a particular production unit with which a contract has been made to supply certain products to a particular using unit.[13] Verification of the quality of the goods delivered can then be ensured by the central office which is responsible to the user for this quality as well as for the honouring of delivery-dates and specifications.
Respect for the norms of allotment which have been laid down centrally may also be ensured through the intervention of the banking system. This is done by assigning to each production-unit which uses certain products credits that cannot be used except for obtaining these products. When this is done, the using enterprises can obtain those goods covered by this credit-appropriation system only within the limits of the credits assigned to them for this purpose. This amounts to temporarily depriving part of the money in circulation of its role as universal equivalent.
(It is to be observed that, in any case, the role of money as universal equivalent is played only to a greatly reduced extent inside the socialist state sector as it operates in the Soviet Union, owing to the fact that use of the circulating funds held in money form by the different enterprises is subordinated to the actual requirements of the economic plan.)
Through the mechanism of "credit-appropriations" the banking system is used as an instrument for carrying out in a relatively flexible way a plan for the allotment of certain products which has been drawn up centrally. In this case, however, the using enterprise can choose its own supplier and fix the delivery date it wants, and also, perhaps, specify some other points in connexion with the order it places. In some circumstances the existence of such freedom of choice for the using enterprises may be essential for efficient management of the economy.
When such freedom of choice is needed, but a centralised method of allotment is arbitrarily imposed instead (the productive forces not yet
page 59
ready for such a method), the consequence may be a veritable squandering of resources: products arriving too soon or too late at the using enterprises (which have no way of either refusing to accept products sent them by a central administration or hastening the despatch of goods from the centre), mistakes in specifications, and so on.
It may be noted that the banking system can be used as agent for supervising the execution of a plan of allotment drawn up centrally but carried out in a flexible manner, even when relatively scarce products are being allotted. This is a method which can be very much superior, through its very flexibility, to a purely administrative method. It does in fact make possible, without recourse to price-manipulations (which in some cases would be ineffective), the adjustment of total demand to total supply.
To illustrate the foregoing, let me take as an example a country where, over a certain period, the demand for fertiliser has shown a spontaneous tendency to exceed supply (the latter being restricted by capacities for production and import). The demand could be restricted by several different methods:
(1) By decisions taken on the plane of the commodity categories; for example, by raising the prices at which the fertilisers are sold to the using units.
From a wrongly abstract view of things, this would "always" be the economically most effective method, for it would restrict the use of fertilisers to those users alone who were capable of getting the maximum increase of production from them (i.e., using profitably even very expensive fertilisers). Actually, this is not necessarily so, for the users are far from always capable of forecasting in a serious way the increase in yield and receipts they can obtain through using a given quantity of fertiliser. Under these conditions, a rise in the price of fertilisers will restrict the demand from units managed by the most cautious or most timid administrators, while having little effect on the demand from those who do not worry much about profitability. A more efficient use of fertilisers will thus not have been achieved, and, moreover, it may prove necessary, in order to restrict demand sufficiently, to raise prices to levels having no proportion any longer to production-costs. This may happen at the beginning of a period of accelerated development, when a substantial section of the "cadres" are still lacking in any very precise notion of economic calculation and the conditions in which it can be undertaken.
(2) By adopting a centralised allotment procedure which is non-administrative, i.e., which is technico-economic in character. In this case, for example, each production-unit will be assigned (on the basis of a more or less well-founded estimate, economic and technical, such as could be made by a regional management centre or an agrotechnical service which had studied the increases in yield obtained during a recent period in different production-units as a result of their use of fertiliser) credits specially "appropriated" to the purchase of fertilisers, and this under conditions such that the total amount of these credits is equal to the total value of the
page 60
fertilisers distributed, at the prices at which they are supplied to the using enterprises.
(3) By adopting an administrative method of allotment. In this case, for example, each production-unit will be required to present a demand in advance to an administrative authority. The latter, after examining these demands, will assign a given amount of fertiliser to each production-unit. This procedure can be effective only if the administration in charge of allotment possesses sufficient technical knowledge to ensure the optimum allotment and if it is in a position to respond rapidly to the demands it receives.
If, however, this is not the case, in other words, if allotment is not ensured by a competent technical organ but by a bureaucratic apparatus, it is likely that administrative semi-paralysis will result, with a multiplicity of authorities bearing responsibility for making decisions. Thus, in Cuba in 1963, demands for fertiliser had to go through seven or eight administrative authorities, and the latter might take eleven months to respond to the demands they received. Naturally, replies made in this way, after consultation with various authorities which were often remote from the using units, might, when they came, no longer bear any relation to the objective needs of these units.
In the various instances in which the allotment of products no longer depends on the users' choice, whether because of "shortage" or for reasons connected with the striving for optimum social allotment of certain products,[14] we see, instead of the allotment of resources by way of the market (a method of allotment which may survive, to a certain extent, even inside the socialist sector, within the limits laid down by the plan, so that this market is no longer a "free" market but one which is under social control), either a technico-economic method of allotment or else an administrative one.
In either of these two instances, the role played by the commodity categories is blunted, together with that of the relative autonomy of the production-units. The link between these two phenomena is thus once again confirmed, while the conditions for their departure from history are made apparent, namely: the appearance of the possibility and necessity of effective social forecasting calculations, that is, of calculations which can cover not merely the total quantities of the various products to be supplied during a certain period, but also the qualities that these products must possess and the place and time for their best utilisation.
However, as already said, the cases I have mentioned form only one of the categories of phenomena that presage the disappearance of economic subjects endowed with a certain degree of autonomy, and so also the disappearance of commodity categories as these still manifest themselves within the state sector of the socialist economy.
b) Centralised economic management of certain branches of production.
by the central authority on the opportuneness of this delivery) and the products they supply are also governed by allotment instructions. In such cases there is no longer buying and selling but, instead, circulation of products and currency tokens.[15]
Of course, when products are supplied free of charge by a central authority to production-units dependent upon it, but continue to be "purchased" by this central authority, it is only the level at which commodity exchange is taking place that has been shifted.
Such a change of level may, however, be of considerable importance, and this for several reasons, of which I will mention here only those that seem to me the major ones:
(1) The change in the level at which commodity exchange takes place can result in a reduction, sometimes a drastic one, in the number of participants in these exchanges within the state sector of the socialist economy. When the quantitative change reaches a certain scale, it has a qualitative significance: it means, in fact, a considerable reduction in the social importance of the commodity categories. In particular, when in a given branch of activity only one economic subject is left, this can mean that economic calculation is henceforth carried on only on the plane of that branch, and no longer below that plane.
(2) A change like this in the level of participation in commodity exchange can make possible an extremely exact ex post calculation of the quantities of labour actually expended per production-unit. This calculation is then, indeed, much easier than that which can be carried out when there are a considerable number of economic subjects in being, all supplying the same sort of products, but themselves supplied under conditions which are various and hard to ascertain.
(3) A change of level like this also makes it possible to cause the labour time actually expended to coincide more and more closely with what is socially necessary for the satisfaction of social needs.
When, in fact, a given product, or category of products, is supplied by a single economic subject and, on the other hand, the objective conditions are present for this economic subject really to dominate the activity of the technical units which are subordinated to it, this economic subject can make optimum use of the production-capacity of the subordinate technical units, to such a degree that it can be said that the labour actually expended is virtually equal to that which is socially necessary.
This presupposes, of course, a development of the productive forces such that the domination of a single economic subject over the various technical units subordinate to it is a real and not merely an apparent domination, like that, for example, we see in the case of a bureaucratic administrative "domination". Actually, this latter type of "domination", just because it is not founded upon genuine economic integration, leads to the taking of arbitrary decisions which are the result of unavoidable ignorance of the concrete conditions in which the various subordinate units operate and the requirements that follow from these.
page 63
Any attempt by a purely administrative authority to "dominate" the activity of production-units which are not really and organically inter-connected can result only in misuse of the productive forces and therefore in squandering the labour-time required in order to obtain a certain volume of production. In such cases the labour-time actually expended is greater than what is socially-necessary, in consequence of bad organisation, that is, of lack of correspondence between juridical relations and real production relations.
(4) Finally, and most important, the appearance of a single economic subject at the level of a certain number of important branches of production makes possible social forecasting calculation which is much more exact than what can be accomplished when a multitude of production-units exist. Through a development like this we can see the objective conditions coming about for a kind of planning which is no longer restricted to giving social direction to the productive forces (which was already a decisive change as compared with a market economy, since it represented a leap from the realm of necessity into that of freedom, as Engels puts it), but which amounts, to an ever-increasing extent, to total social control of the productive forces.
Care must be taken, though, and this needs repeating, that the appearance of a single economic subject at the level of a branch of the national economy is based upon the realisation of quite definite objective conditions (to which I shall come back again when I analyse the concept of "economic subject"). If one tried to anticipate these objective conditions by setting up a juridical subject which does not correspond to an economic subject, then, far from causing the conditions to arise for control of the productive forces, the risk would be run of losing even the means of giving them direction. In this case, indeed, one would be trying to establish the level at which economic decisions are taken elsewhere than where there is actual knowledge both of the conditions under which these decisions can be applied and of the concrete consequences which can result from these decisions. Thus, instead of establishing an organisation capable of acting consciously, there would have been established one doomed to act, to some extent at least, blindly.
Having said this, it is obvious (as I have already pointed out in another context) that some juridical steps may, provided they are accompanied, or followed, by adequate technical changes, create conditions which can hasten, in a socially satisfactory way, a reduction in the number of economic subjects, and thus also in the sphere of operation of the commodity categories.
As a general rule, however, the taking of juridical steps, which can speed up a reduction in the number of economic subjects does not mean the establishment of a single state enterprise at the level of an entire branch of production before the objective conditions for this are present. In Cuba, for example, in the Ministry of Industries, the setting-up of "Consolidados", each managing an entire branch of industry, has given only indifferent
page 64
results in every case where the conditions were not present for a large number of units to be managed from a single decision-making centre of an economic kind.
Similarly, the powers of intervention in the management of production units which were accorded at one time to the Soviet trusts or to the Chief Administrations of the Ministries (Glavki) very often had harmful consequences for good economic management, at least whenever the objective conditions were not ripe for this centralised management or this central intervention in the current management of the enterprises as a real possibility and an economic necessity, and not a mere administrative measure.[16]
A method which, in some cases, may lead to a progressive reduction in the number of economic subjects is the establishment, at the level of each branch (on the national or the regional scale, depending on the particular case) of a central office for selling the products of this branch.[17]
At an initial stage, an organ of this kind may restrict itself to centralising all orders for the products of the given branch and allotting the fulfilment of these orders among different production-units, taking into account their production-capacity, their labour-costs, their costs of production, their location, and so on. In order to carry out a task like this in a socially useful way, that is, non-bureaucratically, such a central office must not be set up until conditions are present which enable this central office really to know the characteristics of the different production-units to which it sends orders, and the circumstances in which these orders will be fulfilled. In practice, this presupposes either that there are only a small number of comparatively homogeneous units[18] or that there are centralised means of electronic recording and calculation, that is to say, generally speaking, a level of development of the productive forces which is already high.
When this is not so, the premature introduction of a form of integration, even of the sort just mentioned, instead of playing a useful economic role, is merely administrative in significance and, far from contributing to the concentration of responsibilities and decisions, causes them to be dissipated in a bureaucratic administration. This may render economic calculations very difficult or even impossible, as happens, for example, when the financial autonomy of the production-units is arbitrarily abolished or restricted.
On the other hand, however, when central sales offices have been set up on sound technical foundations, they may become, from a certain moment onward, that is, on the basis of further progress of the productive forces, centres for the supply of raw materials or intermediate products to the units whose activity they co-ordinate. They may then become progressively transformed into management centres.
The production-units they manage may eventually cease to be economic subjects and become nothing more than "technical departments" of an integrated complex economic group. If this happens, we have before us a type of functional centralisation which is profoundly different from bureaucratic centralisation. This functional centralisation may, however, leave, so
page 65
far as certain decisions are concerned, a relatively wide sphere of initiative to the various "working groups" or "technical departments" that make up this integrated complex economic group. This too is a problem to which I shall come back.
This, then, appears to be one of the lines along which the disappearance of the commodity categories from within the state sector of the socialist economy may be prepared. This line is analogous to "horizontal concentration" in the capitalist economy.[19]
Another line along which the progressive disappearance of the commodity categories can take place is that of vertical integration, also sometimes called "vertical concentration".
c) Vertical integration of economic activities.
Another consequence of specialisation can be, on the contrary, that a physical production-unit specialises to the point that it is meeting the needs of a single user only, that is, of one other physical production-unit.[20] When this happens, we have integration of the activity of the first unit into the activity of the second. Thenceforth it will be the latter that will completely decide the volume and characteristics of the former's production, so that it tends no longer to be an autonomous economic subject. It becomes increasingly a technical department of an integrated group which transcends it. At a certain moment, when the integrated group belongs to a single owner, the products coming from the units "up-stream" no longer have to be sold, they flow down towards the using department. The sphere of operation of the commodity categories is thus reduced.
page 66
The formula of the Soviet "combine" provides an example of a process of vertical integration like this.
In another form, the Sovnarkhozy tend towards flexible methods of integration, when they achieve organic co-operation between complementary production-units under their authority.
Vertical integration, as is well known, takes place on a large scale in capitalist economy. It goes on in all branches of industry (motor-cars, steel-works integrated with mining, chemicals, and so on). This process is now spreading to agriculture, and is tending to transform in a far-reaching way the relations between agriculture and industry.
Inside capitalist agriculture examples become more and more plentiful of stock-raising units (especially in poultry-farming) which, "up-stream", integrate the breeding of the animals or birds, the production of feeding-stuffs for them and the industrial processing of these feeding-stuffs, and, "down-stream", integrate the slaughterhouses and the treatment of by-products (or else are themselves integrated in these activities). These phenomena of integration have technical foundations which determine their forms and their limits. Thus, for the raising of poultry it is the slaughterhouse that, at the moment, is the "production-unit" which integrates the other activities and to which they are subordinate. It is this unit, too, which by its size determines that of the integrated group.
This "technical link" may itself be dominated by a more decisive "economic link". This happens when a group of slaughterhouses (and of the stockraising units which they dominate) is itself dependent on a commercial chain which determines to some extent the volume of consumption and production, by practising a certain policy as regards selling-prices to consumers and buying-prices to producers. The geographical placing of the various "technical links" will then be determined by a particular economic strategy, and will lead to the structuring of the space round about on a technico-economic basis, the distances between each "technical link" and its suppliers being more or less programmed.
Phenomena comparable to this appear also in the canning of milk, fruit, vegetables, and so on. In these activities, the tinning or bottling works tends to structure and dominate a large part of the space surrounding it.
The concrete forms taken by such phenomena of capitalist integration are very diverse. In some cases the units producing "raw materials" belong to the factory where these are processed, which in turn may belong to a chain of distributors. In other cases (at present most frequent), the supply of "raw materials" continues to be ensured by agricultural entrepreneurs who remain juridically independent. Even in this case, though, the actual management of the agricultural units is progressively integrated in that of the industrial unit. It is the latter that decides in advance the quantity of products that it is to receive, their quality, and the dates and intervals for delivery, and it is also the industrial unit that, very often, delivers to its suppliers the raw materials that they are to process, and which, in general,
page 67
provides the technical leadership of the agricultural units (or at least of the sections of these units which work for it).
There is obviously need to investigate whether the separation between the ownership of the agricultural enterprises and the ownership of the factory for which they work (a separation which means that what we have here is an integration of the contractual type ) is a reflexion, on the basis of private property, of certain technical requirements (represented, for instance, by the requirements of crop-rotation), or whether it merely represents a method used by industrial capital to relieve itself of the risks involved in agriculture and to increase its profits by keeping down the prices paid to agricultural enterprises which are made more and more dependent on it.
It is also to be noted that in many tropical countries the sugar refineries form an organic grouping with the cane-fields, whether the refineries are the owners of all or part of the fields or whether they are connected with the owners of the cane-fields by crop-contracts. When such organic groups exist, this makes possible a detailed overall "programming" of the production operations.[21]
It also happens, of course (and the ultimate result is technically the same) that a group of agricultural entrepreneurs set up, in the form of a co operative, an industrial unit for processing their products. In this case we have vertical integration proceeding from "up-stream".
Although, for the time being, vertical integration (organically linking agriculture and industry) has up to now not gone very far in the socialist countries (where, however, the formula of the "agro-industrial combine" has been studied and even tried out in a number of instances),[22] this phenomenon of integration seems to correspond to the requirements of the development of modern productive forces and therefore must also constitute one of the lines along which an increasing number of economic subjects will wither away, with a correlative withering-away of the sphere of operation of the commodity categories.
On the other hand, as I have already mentioned, the Sovnarkhozy are endeavouring to promote organic co-operation among some of the industrial units operating under their authority. Co-operation of this sort may also lead to some form of vertical integration.
Similarly, in the USSR (and in other socialist countries), the horizontal or vertical integration of economic activities can develop on the basis of agreements made directly between different industrial enterprises. It may even happen that in some cases such agreements can engender a new juridical personality (this is what has occurred with the so-called "Soviet firm").[23] Such a juridical personality usually corresponds to a new economic subject which tends to re-structure, technically and economically, the activities of the enterprises which have formed it.
Altogether, whatever may be the methods by which the integration of economic activities takes place, this corresponds to a group of economic and technical changes which tend to reduce progressively the number of eco-
page 68
nomic subjects, and, in correlation with this, the sphere of operation of the commodity categories.
Presented in schematic fashion, these changes take place essentially in three forms, which I shall call:
(1) Unilinear integration, which means the entry of a production-unit into a "series" within which it loses all economic autonomy. The activity of this unit is then wholly dictated by the needs of the "head" unit (that is, the unit which realises or disposes of the products of the integrated unit).
(2) Multilinear integration, which means the affiliation of several production-units to another economic unit. The latter may be responsible either for processing operations, or transport, or distribution, and may be the only one in contact with the "rest" of the economy, either for disposing of the products of the integrated group or else for both disposing of the products and for supplying the integrated group with the products it needs.
This can lead to the establishment of conditions of management of the affiliated units based on the "head" unit (or "terminal" unit), whether these affiliated units all supply the same kind of products or whether they each supply complementary products (as happens, for example, with motor-car factories which receive certain items from "suppliers" who are attached to them exclusively).
(3) Multi-integration. This means the regular affiliation of a number of production-units to a number of user-units which absorb the whole of their production. This can occur in the case of agricultural units producing a variety of crops and disposing of each category of produce to a different processer, each processer controlling that section of the productive activity of these producers which concerns it.[24]
Rather than talk of "multi-integration", it would perhaps be preferable to use the expression "ramified integration" or "integration by networks", so as to bring out the fact that the integration in question takes place in several directions and along lines which may intersect at a variety of levels. It is possible that this type of integration "by networks" may be the one that best corresponds, for the moment, to the nature of modern productive forces in certain sectors of the economy.
The sector in which this type of integration seems, at the moment, destined to take an especially important place is that of the chemical industry. In this industry the different production-units necessarily have to maintain close and reciprocal inter-relations. To convince oneself of this it is enough to see the dimensions assumed, under capitalism, by the big companies that produce chemicals. There is the well-known example of the Du Pont de Nemours company, in the U.S.A. The turnover of this company is of the order of $2,000,000,000 and it employs about 150,000 people.[25]
In Germany, the three big chemical firms (Bayer, Badische Anilin, Hoechst) each have a turnover of around $600-700,000,000. They each employ about 50,000 people and invest nearly $100,000,000 every year.
page 69
In France this form of concentration of the chemical industry is much less advanced, but nevertheless there are two powerful chemical firms: Rhône-Poulenc, with a turnover of more than $200,000,000 and "Produits Chimiques Pechiney-Saint-Gobain", which comes next, with 17 factories and two research centres, the whole employing 11,500 people and supplying, in certain fields (chlorine, sulphuric acid, superphosphates) two-fifths or more of France's total production -- even more than half in some branches (e.g., polyvinyl chloride).
The offices and affiliates of big companies of this kind keep up regular relations among themselves and maintain joint services for much of their buying and selling.
From the standpoint both of the current working of the production units and of their use of research services and their investment policy, this amounts to making a huge productive group into a single economic subject. Some, of course, of the production-units affiliated to a group like this are less integrated with it than others, and consequently retain a distinct personality, economic and juridical. This is the case, for instance, with the "subsidiary companies" of a certain number of large trusts in the capitalist chemical industry. To some extent the retention of these separate juridical personalities reflects compromises reached between financial groups, the sharing of risks and the seeking of certain advantages in respect of taxation.
In a socialist economy, the reasons for survival of the distinct juridical personality of the production-units integrated in a technico-productive group are obviously less numerous than in a capitalist economy, but it may happen, nevertheless, that such reasons are present, and integration will then be only partial, leaving a certain number of economic subjects each "their own personality", though with reduced functions.
At a further stage of integration, within the framework of the socialist economy, a growing proportion of the production-units are bound to lose their character as economic subjects, while retaining a certain economic or social personality within the group. This economic or social personality may be marked by the capacity of the production-units to take certain subordinate economic decisions (usually subject to ratification by the responsible organs of the overall management of the integrated complex ).
The various forms of integration, when these develop in a socialist economy, can thus give rise to a relatively small number of "large productive economic complexes" of international, national, regional or local significance, the different sections of which may be governed by internal technical planning. This increasingly cuts down the number of units which are in irregular or occasional contact with each other and makes increasingly easy the effecting of a priori adjustments of production activities. This raises the plan from the level of direction of the productive forces (dealt with as branches of activity regarded as statistical or administrative groups sub-divided into a certain number of economic subjects ) to the level of domination of the productive forces, dealt with as large economic complexes of a functional nature.
page 70
These are the objective bases of the far-reaching changes that take place in production-relations, i.e., in the relations established among the producers.
The increasing integration of productive activities carries further the interdependence of these activities which is already developing fast under capitalism, and which established the objective basis for the first stage of planning. Within the framework of socialism, this integration goes forward in the state sector and in the co-operative sector, while, little by little, in a variety of ways, whatever of the private sector has managed to survive for a time becomes incorporated in these other sectors.
The juridical "forms" through which the integration of economic activities occurs may be extremely various. It may happen through the forms already referred to, or through others, such as agreements between co-operatives, agreements between co-operatives and state enterprises, mergers between state enterprises, etc. I do not propose to examine these juridical forms in themselves but merely to consider the influence these changes have on planning.
In short, it can be said that, as a result of these changes, when they have taken place on a sufficient scale, economic planning can really become, on the plane of production, the determining of the current needs of individual consumers, communities and "productive economic complexes ", and the assignment of precise tasks corresponding to these needs to each of the production complexes.
This assignment of definite tasks cannot, of course, be fully effective unless it is founded on knowledge available centrally of the capacities of these complexes and the conditions under which they work.
When this is present, the irregularity of the relationship between production and consumption (which necessitates unforeseeable adjustments) can disappear completely, and the problem that formerly confronted each economic subject, of finding its "suppliers" or those who would absorb its products, also disappears.
Socialisation of the means of production becomes complete when the number of economic subjects is sufficiently reduced for their activity and development to be really subject to social control, that is, when society can really use the productive forces as a whole in a conscious way, in order to satisfy needs of which it is aware.
Automation of production and the production and introduction of electronic tools of management provide the material foundation which makes it possible to define, with ever-greater precision and exactness, the means that have to be set to work in order to satisfy social needs, but the precise determining of these needs themselves, in so far as they arise outside the sphere of production, implies the attainment of social and institutional conditions that are at present only in process of formation and which it would therefore be premature to try to define in detail as of now.
It is at the moment when society has achieved full control of its productive forces, and can completely determine its needs, that the commodity
page 71
categories will lose all utility: this can be conceived only as the end-result of an historical process consciously conducted towards this culmination.
In the foregoing passages, the terms "economic subjects" and "juridical subjects" have been used. The context itself in which they were used has explained what they mean adequately for the needs of my analysis. Now, however, I must examine these expressions, in order to try and define them more precisely, something that could not be done at an earlier stage.
5 Economic subject and juridical subject
The chief problems that arise here are as follows:
I shall now briefly examine some aspects of these problems.
a) Determining the economic subjects.
(3) A high degree of interdependence in the activity of these groups.
This is indeed where the problem arises: "where are the real economic subjects located?" It is this complex case that I will examine.[26]
If we proceed from the foregoing analysis we shall say that the level at which the economic subject is located varies according to the degree of development of the productive forces, the character of the productive forces set to work, in the different sectors or branches of the economy, and the
page 73
nature of the decisions that have to be taken, since it is the criterion of the possible social efficiency of decisions that will also make it possible to determine what the various real economic subjects are. If we take once again the example of electric power production, we see that this can have a highly developed structure, i.e., can depend on a number of power stations each of which has its own "physical personality", but we also see that centralised management of all the electric power stations of a country, even a large one, can be ensured when these stations are linked together and a system of rapid transmission of information, between the various stations and the centre, has been established, together with a corresponding system of transmission of orders from the centre to the stations.
In a case like this, the economic subject, i.e., the "production-complex" at the level of which the most efficient economic decisions can be taken, is the branch as a whole which produces and distributes electric power. The separate power-stations are, in relation to this economic subject, merely technical departments at the level of which no truly efficient economic decision can be taken, since it is not there but at the centre that it can be decided, on the basis of programming and calculations carried out by electronic instruments, which works should be set in operation at any given moment and which should have their functioning slowed down or suspended.
Similarly, we have seen that the oil-refining industry can also, though to a lesser extent, be managed centrally (on the scale of a large region or a small country). Here again, the most efficient management of the refineries as a whole can be ensured by a centre which takes account of the needs that have to be met in different parts of the country and determines, taking the variable factors into account, the points to which the crude oil should be sent for refining and those to which the refined oil should be distributed. In this case, too, the economic subject may coincide with a given branch of industry.
On the other hand, in activities lacking the characteristics mentioned, it is necessary to decide concretely the level at which the real economic subjects are, that is, those that are really in a position to use efficiently the given means of production.
Depending on circumstances, this level will correspond either to an industrial establishment (i.e., a works) or to a group of works which themselves are either specialised or else interlinked in a relatively rigid and permanent way by the supplies they furnish each other with. An especially important case is that where there is technical integration of different production units and, consequently, the appearance, at the level of the "integrated complex" (which, as we have seen, may take the form of a combine, for instance), of a specific economic subject.
In the case of agricultural activities, the level at which the real economic subject is located corresponds, in the present state of the productive forces, to a working group which is usually much less extensive than in industry, owing especially to the large number of variables that have to be reckoned
page 74
with in carrying on effective agricultural production, the range of fluctuations to which these variables are subject, and, last but not least, the still preponderant role played by direct individual human action (including at the level of observation) in agricultural production.
The foregoing remarks are essentially intended to illustrate the way that the problem presents itself -- the problem of deciding the economic subjects on which, at a certain level of development of the productive forces and with certain characteristics of the latter, it is necessary to confer a juridical personality so as to enable these subjects to utilise with maximum efficiency the means of production at their disposal.
What we have to do in fact, is to work out a theory of the economic subject. So far, we are a long way from having worked out such a theory, and the decisions taken to endow certain working groups with juridical personality include a large element of empiricism.
In default of a fully-worked-out theory of the economic subject in the production sphere of a socialist economy, it is possible to say, first, that the economic subject constitutes the place where multiple and irregular relationships with a variety of units of production, of distribution, and (or ) of consumption are brought together. It is the multiplicity and irregularity of these relations that calls for economic choices to be made, and which makes of a group of workers an economic subject.
In other words, the economic subject forms one of the fundamental links in a division of labour which is not yet entirely organic. That is why it is at this level that current economic decisions have to be made and the corresponding obligations undertaken. That is why it is necessary to endow each economic subject with its own juridical personality and financial resources, so as to enable it to fit itself flexibly (which does not mean independently of the economic plan) into the process of the social division of labour.
The various shortcomings of a system which mutilates the economic subject of the functions which alone enable it to undertake in a coherent way the tasks of production and of expanded reproduction in which it is involved have been amply revealed by all the negative experiences resulting from administrative management of the economy.
Administrative management leads to choices being made by an authority different from the economic subject, an authority which lacks the information possessed by the economic subject and which is incapable of assuming effectively the responsibilities incumbent on the latter. It leads to the bureaucratisation of the economy, to an increasingly falsified view of reality. It brings subjective factors into the drawing up of plans, to an extent that increases with the distance between the economic subjects and the level at which choices are made, and this puts more and more obstacles in the way of the formulation of a coherent overall economic policy, let alone its execution.
In the light of these remarks, it is clear that the attribution of certain juridical powers to an economic subject, powers which may make a juridical subject of it, and the nature of these powers, must depend:
page 75
(1) On the nature of the decisions to be taken, and, in particular, on the more or less extensive social area they affect.
(2) On the number of technical and economic variables that have to be taken into consideration in order to secure a satisfactory economic solution, from the standpoint of the national economy. The number of these variables must be considered from at least two aspects:
On the one hand, the economic complex to which juridical personality is assigned must not be so extensive that the number of variables or the amount of information that have to be taken into account at the level of this complex are such that, in practice, it is not possible to take a decision based on a correct and adequate study of these variables or this information. It is, in particular, a consideration of this order that may make it necessary to delimit an agricultural economic unit as an economic and juridical subject at a level of size that may be regarded as smaller than the optimum from the standpoint of the use of certain material means of production. Hence, for example, the situation which existed at one time in the USSR, where the comparatively small collective farms had superimposed upon them the Machine and Tractor Stations each of which served several of these farms.
On the other hand the economic complex to which powers of decision making are assigned must be large enough for it to have effectively available a sufficient amount of information and decision-making power,[27] because only on this condition can it manage efficiently, from the standpoint of the national economy, the productive forces that fall within its sphere of action.
In this respect it can be said, for example, that to attribute a distinct decision-making power to each electric power station would create a situation in which the juridical subject would not possess either the information or the power needed for it to use the productive forces in the most efficient way, on the national scale.
Nevertheless, this aspect of the matter can only be taken into consideration if the fact of transferring the decision-making power to a higher level does not give rise to a juridical subject which is incapable of controlling in practice all the factors on which it has to rely in taking satisfactory decisions and in getting them applied in an effective way. What, in fact, signalises the existence of an economic subject is precisely its capacity to control a group of productive forces.
These various observations are already bringing us to perceive the need to accept, in certain cases, the existence of a hierarchy of economico-juridical subjects, each endowed with distinct powers, depending on the nature of the decisions to be taken.
Thus, for example, the centralised management of a group of electric power stations can deal only with the problems of supplying these stations and with the scale of their current operations. Decisions affecting investment, however, have to be made at another, higher level, where it is possible to take account of the different requirements of general economic and social
page 76
development; while, contrariwise, decisions regarding the internal organisation of labour, recruitment, maintenance of buildings, and the like, have to be made at the level of each power station taken individually. These last-mentioned decisions will themselves, of course, have to fit into the overall framework of directives and regulations. This therefore leaves surviving at the level of each power station either an "economic subject" with very limited functions or else a working group with a certain "social personality".
1) Internal structuring of economic subjects and working groups.
The technical basis of the work brigade (which, in certain cases, is organised around a group of tractors) constitutes one of the elements which influence very markedly the actual size of such a working group. But the question also arises of the conditions under which each brigade may have a certain permanence, by being (as suggested by D. Muratov) responsible for a whole year for certain tracts of land.[28] Finally, the fundamental problem is, it would seem, that of the conditions for precise responsibility and collective initiative (on the basis of a certain technique); this problem is located at the level of the relations between the members of the group and the relations between the group and other groups, that is, at the level of concrete production-relations.
Similar problems obviously arise within the state farms as well. The latter may be divided into "workshops" and "sections" which possess a certain permanence and the "optimum" size of which also has to be determined.
Here again we find a problem of very great complexity, especially in agriculture, namely, the problem of the "optimum size " of the working groups.
Theoretical analysis enables us to define the nature of the problems arising here, but the decisive instrument for getting a concrete answer to a concrete question is the carrying out of economic calculation. The latter will, of course, give a correct answer only if the problem is first presented in meaningful theoretical terms.
Economic calculation like this must make it possible to compare the efficiency of different kinds of organisation. It must be emphasised that the efficiency of a given type of organisation includes a variety of aspects. We must distinguish between short-term efficiency (i.e., efficiency at the level of how economically the available means of production are currently being used) and longer-term efficiency. In agriculture, for instance, the latter is shown in the influence exerted by a certain type of organisation on conservation or improvement of soil characteristics. More generally, this efficiency is shown in the influence of the type of organisation on the capacity of the working groups to adapt themselves to innovations or even to promote them, and so on.
The problem is thus much more complex than it seems at first glance.[29]
The problem of optimum size does not, of course, concern only the working groups "at the grass roots" but also the economic subjects made up of several working groups. There too it is in agriculture that the problem appears in its fullest complexity. In industry, the technical foundations for the sizes of working groups are determined in a much more obvious way by certain material factors: for example, the optimum size of blast furnaces or of rolling-mills determines very largely the combination of other material factors of production which technically have to be associated with them, and, consequently, the size of the economic subjects that will manage a given technical group. As I have already remarked, however, it can happen that what appears to be the optimum size at a purely material level may cause problems of co-ordination such that the economically optimum size does not coincide with the technically optimum size.
page 78
In agriculture the question is further complicated by the dispersal of activities in space, the problems of crop-rotation, of adequately intensive employment of machines in seasonal use, etc.
The question of the "cadres" available (and this is obviously true for industry as well, or any other economic activity) may also have an influence on what, at a given moment, may constitute the optimum size of certain economic subjects. This is an extremely important aspect of the matter.
Thus, in the Soviet Union, during the ploughing up of the "virgin lands", it was to some extent the problem of agricultural cadres that led to the formation of giant state farms (109,000 hectares was the average in Kazakhstan). Accordingly, as the number of agricultural cadres increased, it was decided to reduce this average size (cf. the discussion in the Central Committee of the Soviet Communist Party, February 1964).
Similarly, in Cuba, the size of the Granjas del Pueblo, though too big for efficient management, was dictated by the inadequate number of cadres available. The same reason was invoked for not according financial autonomy to the Granjas del Pueblo and confirming it, in 1963, to the Agrupaciones basicas (which embrace several Granjas ). It is intended eventually to confer juridical personality and financial autonomy on every granja.[30]
The problems of the internal structuring of the people's communes in China are clearly of the same order as those mentioned above. We know that economic and juridical personality was accorded to work-brigades (i.e., the former co-operatives) and also to work-teams formed within the brigades.
Thus, in an article in the People's Daily of 21 December 1960, entitled: "Property on three levels based on brigade property and the fundamental system of the people's communes at the present time", we read:
Commenting on this paragraph from the People's Daily, Liu Jo-chin, in a study published in the review Jingli Yanjiu, organ of the Economic Institute of the Chinese Academy of Sciences, writes that this passage:
page 79
The plan must be decided on by the members of the commune and not by the higher levels, from above and rigidly.
The author adds that the passage:
This brings up, as already mentioned in passing, the problem of internal economic calculation, that is, economic calculation at the level of the different working groups. This calculation is obviously not the same thing as the financial autonomy with which economic subjects can be endowed. It will doubtless have to continue even after the commodity categories have passed away.[31]
What has been said also brings up the problem of the link between quality of work at the level of the working group and the payment of the group's members.
Thus, in the state farms as at present organised in the USSR, the wages paid to each worker are, as a rule, calculated essentially on the basis of the work done by the individual, which since accounting takes place at the level of the state farm as a whole, means that this accounting is very complicated and it is not easy to check concretely on the quality of the work done by each worker. For example, in a report of 25 December 1959, Nikita Khrush-
page 80
chev mentioned a state farm where payment of workers required the maintenance of 15,000 cards and documents containing, altogether, 1,800,000 items of information, all of which nevertheless failed, he said, "to ensure really exact accounting and control".
Payment at the level of the working group often corresponds more closely to the collective character of the work done, so that payment made to the group can subsequently be shared out among individuals in the group in accordance with socially defined standards. This, of course, presupposes that a high degree of self-discipline and self-checking has been attained, i.e., a high degree of political consciousness. If this is not present, then administrative supervision is inevitable, regardless of its shortcomings.
To conclude these observations on the working groups, it must be stressed that, when the latter are sufficiently stable and their social personality has been correctly defined, they can and must constitute (as we have seen from what has been said above) an essential level for the preparation of plans and checking on their implementation ; from which follows the importance of correct internal structuring of the economic subjects.
These observations thus show us that, inside the production sector of a socialist economy, the economic subjects are, as a rule, subjects which are structured internally. (This structuring will probably have to become more and more complex as the size of the economic subjects grows and integration progresses). The very existence of this internal structuring often makes it hard to distinguish between an economic subject and a working group possessing a social personality.
On this point let me add further that, when the level at which a real economic subject is situated has to be decided, it is very important to take into consideration the delays in transmitting information and in arriving at and notifying decisions. It is necessary to allow, on the one hand, for the maximum interval that can be permitted to elapse between the appearance of a problem and the solution that must be found for it, and, on the other, the interval that inevitably elapses, at a certain stage of organisation and circulation of information, between the moment when this problem appears and that at which a solution can be found for it (this time will obviously vary with the level at which the decisions are taken).
This amounts to recognising, here once more, that determination of the economic subject is conditioned in part by the possibilities of transmitting information, memorising it, and processing it in order to reach decisions, all of which possibilities are connected with the development of the productive forces. Here, too, experience and economic calculation will provide concrete answers. It must be noted in this connexion that the use of simulation techniques can, in some cases, make it possible to avoid excessively repeated, long-drawn-out and costly experiments.[32]
From this standpoint, the size of the economic subjects, their internal organisation and their external links appear to be partly subject to the techniques of collecting, codifying, transmitting, assembling and interpreting information. Included in this "information", of course, are the economic
page 81
or technical decisions that may be taken at various levels. This implies that the advances made in the sphere of information techniques may have considerable practical consequences affecting the size of the real economic subjects and the level at which it is possible to take socially useful decisions.
If, at the stage now reached in these reflexions, I were to try to formulate some of the conclusions that can be provisionally drawn, I should say this:
In present-day socialist economy there are units of production or distribution which bear the character of economic subjects. These units are centres for the appropriation of nature by man or for the sharing-out of the products of this appropriation. They form the framework of a systematically organised technical division of labour.
In so far as the different centres of appropriation or distribution are not linked together organically, or as a result of decisions that can be taken consciously by a higher economic authority, these units constitute links in a local division of labour and are economic subjects each of which has to determine the conditions of its relations with the others, within the limits laid down by the aims of the plan and by the various regulations imposed in order to ensure good co-ordination of the activity of the economic subjects.[33]
As we have seen, each of these units of production or distribution may be subdivided into "working groups". Relations between the latter are determined by the nature of the techniques being used, in so far as these working groups are not themselves economic subjects.
What, in fact, is the mark of an economic subject (in contrast to the working groups that are not economic subjects) is the fact that the products that result from the production-process carried on within an economic subject can be put to manifold and optional uses which cannot be governed by detailed socially useful forecasting, whereas the products that come from a technical unit or working group that is not an economic subject are destined for uses that are determined, or which can be socially determined in advance, in an efficient way.
This is why, as has already been said, the level at which the distinction is made between economic subject and working group varies as time goes by. This level depends on the development of the productive forces, including, of course, the number and competence of the trained personnel, the degree of social consciousness and discipline, the possibilities for collecting and transmitting information, and the possibilities of forward calculation, that are available to the society. The development of the productive forces thus alters the level at which there is or is not complete technical determination, or forward social determination, in a detailed and useful way, of the possible needs for and uses of the various goods emerging from a production process.
One of the characteristics of an economic subject is that it forms a working group (or a complex of working groups) at the level of which economic decisions must be taken.
In contrast to technical decisions (required for the efficient use of a given
page 82
technique in order to achieve given aims ), economic decisions determine the nature and scope of the variable relations that may be established between economic units; thereby, economic decisions also determine the uses that will actually be made of products with many potential uses.
When the economic subject coincides with a production-unit, the economic decisions that can be taken at its level concern essentially the uses to be made either of the products supplied by other economic subjects and which may enter into the production-process for which this unit is responsible, or of the products emerging from the production-process dominated by the economic subject in question.
When, however, the economic subject is responsible essentially for functions of allotment, distribution or management, the economic decisions it can take relate to the uses that will be made of products emerging from a production-process carried on by other economic subjects.
In any case, economic decisions are those which establish, directly or indirectly, relations between economic units, when these relations are not entirely determined by the very nature of the technical processes. Such decisions do not, of course, depend only on the economic subjects.
This leads me to re-emphasise a point made earlier, namely, the need, at a given stage of development of the productive forces, to recognise that there may exist, in one and the same domain but for different types of decision, several economic subjects or administrative authorities hierarchically subordinate one to another, the decision of a particular one of these rather than another being preponderant, depending on the nature of the problems to be solved.
2) Economic hierarchy and administrative or political subordination
According to circumstances, the existence of administrative subordination may give expression either to social necessity or, on the contrary, to a weakness in general economic organisation. In the latter case, it means that an administrative authority has assumed the task of taking economic decisions which it would be better to take at the level of a working group. This can lead to the bureaucratisation of the economy.[34]
The distinction between economic subordination and administrative subordination is not, of course, a matter of legal rules but rather one of the specific features of the authorities concerned. If the higher authority is an integral part of a working group, or a complex of working groups, its domination may express the subordination of the lower authorities to a genuine economic hierarchy; otherwise it is an administrative or political authority.
In a socialist economy, subordination of the economic subjects to administrative or political authorities may result from a variety of situations.
Sometimes this subordination corresponds strictly to the requirements
page 83
of planned development of the economy in the direction of socialism. In this case it expresses the specific conditions in which social priorities are formulated and economic policy applied. This type of subordination may ensure the working out of the decisions which have to be taken at the highest social level. This is so with the main decisions regarding investments, prices, fundamental technical choices and the selection of regions for particular forms of development.
Sometimes this subordination is the only way of ensuring, at least approximately, co-ordination of the current activities of the economic subjects, owing, for example, to the inadequate training of the executives placed at the head of some of the economic subjects.
Sometimes, this subordination merely interferes in decisions that the economic subjects ought to take, because they are better placed to take them. In such cases we have the partial or complete substitution of administrative management for economic management. This substitution may be rendered inevitable, during a certain period, either by political requirements (need for nationalisation measures taken quickly and on a large scale; an economy unbalanced by the strain of war or by economic attacks), or by mistakes in organisation, or by mistakes in economic policy (e.g., a price policy giving rise to "shortages" that render inevitable an administrative rationing of products).
When administrative management tends to go beyond the objective requirements of planning and the development of the economy, it assumes a bureaucratic character. It loses touch with reality. It works slowly, and often in the wrong direction.
When this is the situation, the real economic subjects may react by setting up their own circuits for passing round important information and by following economic rules of conduct which only partly coincide with the decisions taken by the bureaucratic apparatus -- to some extent in order to get round the inadequacies and incompetence of the latter.
There may then exist two different pictures of economic life -- one which can be seen at the level of the economic subjects themselves and another which is composed at the level of the bureaucratic apparatus and in order to satisfy the requirements of this apparatus. This latter picture may sometimes be so distorted as to constitute nothing but a mirage. When this happens, and this "bureaucratic mirage" serves as the basis for plans, these have less and less effect on real economic evolution.
Even apart from the existence of administrative authorities, the fact that there is a hierarchy of subjects means that certain subjects have to take decisions which interfere directly in the activity of others. Such interference must, in principle, always take place in conditions which ensure that the functions and responsibilities of each subject are clearly delimited. If this is not the case, then the efficiency of the whole and the possibilities of checking what actually happens will be greatly reduced.
3) Economic subjects, planning authorities and administrative orders
A fundamental feature of a planned economy is, of course, that the
It must be strongly emphasised that the decisions taken regarding
Now I must say a few words about contractual relations between economic subjects.
The contracts into which economico-juridical subjects enter may be of widely differing content. This is not the place to try and analyse them; I shall therefore confine myself to some very broad indications.
1) Contracts for buying and selling
We have seen, however, that when the plan has laid down in advance the destination, or the source, of certain products, contracts of purchase and sale (which then merely superimpose a contractual obligation upon the obligations arising from the plan) have, to some extent, a formal character: they do not really give expression to the relative autonomy of the economico-juridical subjects. Nevertheless, even when such contracts are made by virtue of the plan, they form, like the payment of the specified price, a condition for the alienation of the products sold by one economic subject and acquired by another. These contracts thus reveal the survival of commodity exchange. The latter is still necessary because the administrative authorities are unable to formulate with sufficient exactitude, in advance, all the directives relating to the conditions of circulation of the products concerned. What cannot be formulated as directives has to take the form of contracts; for example, matters relating to specifications, or delivery dates. The combination of planned tasks and contractual obligations thus appears as what are called "planned contracts".
In the sector of producer co-operatives there are, of course, no such labour contracts between a co-operative and its members: the leaders of the co-operative assign tasks to each member and decide the conditions governing the share-out of the collective product available.
4) Co-operation contracts
Finally, the decisions taken by economic subjects and embodied in contracts can also assume, as we have seen (cf., supra, note 3), the form of agreements for co-operation.
It may be thought that the process whereby exchange and the commodity categories will be eliminated will pass, to some extent, by way of such co-operation agreements between enterprises, which can give rise to new economic and juridical subjects capable of absorbing the subjects which have engendered them. However, this process of contractual integration can usefully serve the development of the productive forces only if it reflects real changes in the nature of these forces and in the degree to which they are socialised.
c) The nature of the decisions to be taken by the different
economic subjects and social authorities
The nature of the decisions that can be taken by the different economico-
page 89
juridical subjects and by the various social authorities, and which affect other economic subjects and social authorities, is closely bound up with the nature of the relations that have to be established between them.
In so far as the relations established between different working groups, economic subjects or social authorities are relations of hierarchical subordination, the decisions taken by the higher authority in relation to the lower are essentially of two types: the regulation and the order.
A regulation is a body of decisions which lays down a framework (i.e., limits) for the activities of the subordinate subjects. It implies autonomy of decision-making by the subordinate subject within the limits of the regulation laid down by the higher authority. The further this regulation goes, and the more detailed it is, the less is the autonomy enjoyed by the subject.
Regulation (emanating from the organs responsible for working out the plan, or from the administration responsible for its application) comes into play when forecasting can assume a general form. In such cases it is possible for the higher authority to base itself upon this forecasting in order to decide, once for all (i.e., until conditions change), the orientation of certain decisions to be taken by the economic subjects. The same can apply, inside a complex economic subject, with regard to the subordinate economic subjects or working groups.
When forecasting of a general kind is not possible, the higher authority can determine certain actions of the hierarchically subordinate subject by giving it a specific order.
Thus, in the planned economies of today, the chief targets to be reached during a certain period by the various economic subjects are laid down by the plan. So far as these economic subjects are concerned, the tasks laid down by the plan constitute orders. It may be that some of the conditions under which these targets have to be reached (e.g., the use of a particular technique) are also laid down by explicit orders. On the other hand, other conditions for attaining these targets, which it would be unhelpful to try to determine from a distance, are governed by decisions taken by each economic subject, within the limits laid down by the regulatory decisions and by the working of the "economic levers" set in operation by virtue of the overall plan.
It is important to recall here that the various working groups or technical units (the workshop, for instance), which together make up an economic subject, essentially receive orders coming from an economic authority inside the subject and responsible either for the general direction of the latter or for the direction of one of its constituent links. It is within this framework that the working groups have to take technical decisions.
Decisions are called "technical" when they concern a production-process the purpose and nature of which have already been entirely laid down by the ruling authority.
A working group which has only the right to decide the material conditions in which the operations entrusted to it are carried out has no economic
page 90
personality. Of course, technical conditions do also, as a rule, involve taking economic efficiency into consideration but, for every group which can take only technical decisions, the framework of calculation of its economic efficiency is wholly and strictly determined from without.
Increasing integration into a complex economic subject of the activities of different production-units (forming parts of the same homogeneous branch or of a chain of units which technically control each other) leads to loss of economic personality by these units, which gradually come to function only in conformity with orders emanating from a central authority, orders which they have to fulfil within the framework of an overall system of regulations. The decisions taken by these units will thus, to an increasing extent, be purely technical decisions.
In a sense, the appearance of economic subjects hierarchically subordinated to each other, when this hierarchical subordination is not arbitrary but corresponds to the nature and degree of development of the productive forces, can be regarded as a transitional phenomenon, the subordinate units being destined to become changed into working groups without any economic personality.
d) The different types of hierarchy
In the foregoing passages a whole number of problems have been left on one side, connected with the taking of decisions at the level of the economic subjects, or the authorities which supervise them. These problems (which call for extensive analysis in their own right) concern the mechanisms which enable an effective decision to be made, the constitution of the organs responsible for taking decisions within each economic subject or each economic authority, the mode of appointment of the members of these organs, and so on.[35] This would take us too far from our main subject, which is the determination of economico-juridical subjects, the nature of the relations that must necessarily be established between them at the present stage of development of the productive forces, and, finally, the effect, on certain aspects of the working out and application of plans, of the existence of commodity categories and of economic subjects. It is this last point that we must now examine.
6 Some problems of planning connected with the existence of
economic subjects
The fact that economic subjects exist in the production sphere, endowed with relative autonomy in decision-making, obviously gives rise to a considerable number of problems as regards the drawing up of plans and the implementing of these plans. I will here touch on only some of these problems.
a) The role played by economic subjects in the drawing up of
plans
In a situation like that, once the targets for the economic subject have been laid down, the tasks of the various technical departments composing it, and the means necessary for realising these tasks, can essentially be determined a priori, provided a certain number of calculations are made. In other words, the chief tasks of the technical departments can be deduced from the targets of the economic subject, allowing for the technical features, in the strict sense, of the various working groups embraced by this subject.[36]
The position is quite different when an economic subject has to take current economic decisions. These decisions have engendered more or less regular relations between it and a more or less considerable number of other economic subjects. In this situation, the conditions in which the plan can foresee the activities of each of the economic subjects in question are quite different: it is not possible to arrive by way of deduction from the targets to be attained by a group of economic subjects at the tasks to be carried out by each of them.
In this situation (that is, when there is a plurality of economic subjects), it is necessary, in order to arrive at plans which are both realisable by each economic subject and economically as advantageous as possible, not merely to consult the working groups and arouse their initiative but also to cause the different economic subjects to participate actively in the actual working out of the plans.
1) Procedures for consultation and participation
It is this situation that confers such importance, weight and significance upon the procedure which consists in preparing centrally a draft plan, sending this "down" to the economic subjects so that they can amend it, and then bringing the amended plan back "up" to the planning centre. This is not merely a calculation technique [37] or a way of assembling relevant information, it is a special way of working out a plan, dictated by the necessity (for the sake of a high degree of social efficiency) of taking into consideration the specific and concrete economic situation of the different subjects.
At a lower level of socialisation of the productive forces than is characteristic of modern industry, that is, in the sectors where this socialisation is relatively less developed, the preparation of the plan cannot yet be under taken by the "sending down" of draft plans and their return, amended, to the central authority. It has to be done by the drawing up at the centre of a simple directional framework, which is handed over to the different economic subjects. The latter then work out, on this basis, their own draft plans. These drafts are sent to the central authority, which makes any necessary adjustments, in a continuing dialogue with the economic subjects. As we saw earlier, this is the way in which, in China, the production plans of the work-teams and work-brigades are prepared within the people's communes, as also the plans of the communes themselves.
It must be observed that, in an increasing number of socialist countries, and notably in the Soviet Union itself,[38] the yearly production plans of the
page 96
industrial enterprises of the state sector itself are to some extent drawn up by this method, that is, starting from drafts prepared by each of the enterprises, within the framework of forecasts of general economic development. These general forecasts result either from a prospective development plan or from directives worked out centrally for a period shorter than that covered by the prospective plan.
One may be surprised to find methods of drawing up the plan which assign a more substantial role to the different economic subjects succeeding methods which had reduced to little the role played by these subjects. There would seem to be grounds for wondering whether the way the methods of drawing up plans is evolving does not refute the conclusions of the foregoing analyses, since what we see is that when the productive forces of the socialist countries have increased and their social character has been consolidated, a bigger role than before is accorded to the economic subjects in the preparation of the plans.
There are several reasons for this evolution, and they show that it does not contradict the conclusions of the foregoing analysis, despite the fact that it seems to be developing in the opposite way to what would be suggested by a mechanical application of the conclusions of this analysis. On this point I will confine myself to listing briefly some of the reasons that account for this type of evolution:
(1) The rapid transition from one mode of production to another, the imbalance and economic tensions caused by it, and by the great efforts made to accumulate, have, during a certain period, created a situation that rendered temporarily impossible the granting to each economic subject of all the margins of initiative, decision-making or suggestion that corresponded to the actual level of development of the productive forces;
(2) The lack of experience of the managers of enterprises, trained personnel and workers likewise made impossible, for an entire period, wider initiative on the part of the economic subjects and wider participation by them in the working out of the plan targets;
(3) What was a necessity at a certain transitional stage (a necessity which, true, was sometimes interpreted excessively), was later looked upon as a mode of organisation appropriate to the level of the productive forces already attained, so that, for a certain period, there was a tendency to treat the productive forces as though they had reached a higher degree of socialisation than was really the case.
In fact, as soon as the problems of the first transitional phase had been overcome, the far-reaching inconveniences of methods of working out the plan which were not appropriate to the level of development of the productive forces (even after these had progressed) made necessary a revision of these methods, in the direction of more extensive autonomy, and a greater measure of initiative and power of suggestion being accorded to the economic subjects.
This process will certainly have to be reversed later on, in consequence of the ever-higher socialisation of the productive forces. However, if we
page 97
accept the foregoing analyses, we have also to accept that this reversal of the process will have to be carried out essentially through reduction in the number of economic subjects and transformation of a considerable quantity of them into mere technical departments of complex economic subjects.
2) Some factors influencing the content of the draft plan
prepared by an enterprise
In the Soviet Union, when the first draft of the plan of an enterprise is sent up to the Sovnarkhoz, the latter has to check whether the economic subject has kept back hidden "reserves" enabling it to surpass the plan. Naturally, when it makes this investigation, the Sovnarkhoz tends as a rule to start from the results achieved in the previous year and to raise them more or less mechanically by a certain percentage, so that the total figures of the enterprise plans come up to the targets set for the region or the whole country. This way of proceeding, which is officially disapproved of, entails a number of disadvantages; it tends to make the plan of the enterprise the result not of an objective evaluation of its potentialities but rather of a compromise between its own estimate, usually a modest one, and the more ambitious estimate, which is not necessarily better founded, of the higher social authority.
b) The degree of exactness and the more or less obligatory
character of enterprise plans
The situation is clearly different where the figures for overall targets are concerned: here a fairly high degree of precision can be attained. What is difficult, at the present level of development of the productive forces, is the endeavour to allot a priori, with precision, all these targets among the different economic subjects. Under present conditions, an a priori allotment like this is very unlikely to be the optimum allotment.[39]
Furthermore, even at the level of the working out of overall plans, that is, of overall targets, certain qualitative aspects of production must today still be left on one side. For example, the plan may well lay down the number of pairs of shoes to be produced during a year; it cannot foresee, in a socially useful way, the styles of shoes that ought to be produced, and still less the number of pairs of each style and the allotment of this specific production among the different factories. Any attempt to go into such details results inevitably in the manufacture of products which are not those most in demand, and so in a waste of social labour. It would be the same if the attempt were made to forecast in a very detailed way the production of different types of equipment. When the latter is highly diversified, corres-
page 99
ponding to a wide variety of conditions of production and use, it is necessary to leave to agreements between enterprises an important role in the specification and destination of what they produce.
The targets and tasks laid down by the plan for each enterprise at the present time in the Soviet Union are essentially the following (so far as industrial enterprises are concerned):
Total amount produced, measured in physical units (by broad categories of products) or in value, at current prices.
Total amount invested, with destination of investments: new building and equipment, modernisation, large-scale repairs.
Principal technical changes (these being minimum targets): machinery to be installed, new processes to be introduced, etc.
Technical norms relating to use of materials and power, and reduction in the consumption of intermediate products (these norms represent maxima in the sense that the quality of the management of an enterprise is estimated by reference to its success in reducing this consumption as compared with the forecasts).
Number of workers and office staff, in broad categories, and total amount of wages to be paid: these estimates are maxima which the enterprise must strive not to exceed, and, if possible, not even to attain; individual wage rates are, of course, fixed on the basis of official scales.
Cost of production per unit of the products (maximum targets).
Selling prices of products. These are compulsory; the prices actually charged must be neither higher nor lower than those laid down. The only exceptions are made for certain products which are new, or are being made in small quantities or even in single specimens. The prices laid down in these cases must be calculated in accordance with certain rules and must be approved by an administrative authority.
Minimum profit, resulting from the difference between cost of production and selling price, and corresponding, in general, to a margin of between 2 and 5 per cent, calculated on the basis of the cost of production.
As will be seen, some of the targets thus laid down by the plan are absolutely obligatory, as, generally speaking, with selling prices; others, on the contrary, are minimum values to be reached and, if possible, surpassed, as with production figures and technical improvements; while yet others are maxima which the enterprise must try, if it can, not to attain, as with the technical norms of consumption of intermediate products and the norms of employment of labour per unit product.
The fact that some targets are maxima or minima that must not be exceeded or must not be attained corresponds to the existence of limits within which the enterprise can operate, something which to some extent gives concrete form to its freedom of manoeuvre.
An essential problem is obviously that of fixing these limits in such a way that within them the enterprise can work out an optimum production-programme.
Another problem is to ensure that the optimum programme in question
page 100
is optimum not only for the particular enterprise but also for society as a whole. These are problems which depend especially on the conditions of economic calculation and planning at the level of the enterprise.
It must, however, be pointed out at once that the freedom of manoeuvre which is necessarily accorded to the economic subject gives rise to important problems in connexion with price policy.
As Oskar Lange observed, in an article published in 1957:[40]
This quotation raises a number of problems regarding price policy which I do not at the moment intend to discuss.[41]
The interest of the quotation so far as our theme is concerned is, in particular, that it shows how it is possible to try and solve one of the contradictions which can arise between the different tasks of the plan, by operating a certain price-policy, that which is proposed in this passage, so as in principle to give the enterprise the directive to seek first and foremost to produce the most profitable goods, the prices of goods being determined in consideration of the social priorities themselves.
In connexion with the foregoing, it is also necessary to make certain observations regarding, on the one hand, the proposals that have been made in the Soviet Union to reduce the number of obligatory tasks laid down in the plan and, on the other, certain contradictions or weaknesses that are at present to be found in business accounting and planning at the level of the enterprise.
One of the disadvantages that appear when too many obligatory tasks are laid upon a particular enterprise is, as has already been shown, the contradiction that may arise between the fulfilment of different tasks.
It is in order to reduce to the minimum such possibilities of contradiction that the Soviet economist Liberman has proposed the following changes regarding the laying down of plans at enterprise level.[42]
(1) That the plans for individual enterprises, after agreement and approval of targets concerning amount and range of goods to be produced, shall be entirely determined by the enterprises themselves, which will thus be allowed to choose for themselves the means of reaching their targets.
(2) In order to ensure that the enterprises maintain a conscientious attitude towards the state and have a material interest in producing as efficiently as possible; that a single fund be established from which payment of all categories of "material incentives" shall be made, the amount of this fund
page 101
depending on profitability, that is, on the profits in relation to the production funds of the given enterprise.
(3) That long-term norms be laid down by the centre to provide a scale of incentives, these incentives being related to the degree of profitability attained by the various branches of production and groups of enterprises which operate in approximately the same natural and technical conditions.
(4) That centralised planning be reinforced and improved by not laying down certain obligatory tasks (control figures) except for the Sovnarkhozy alone. That the practice of allotment of tasks among various enterprises by the Sovnarkhozy in accordance with the "level reached" by these enterprises be abolished. That the Sovnarkhozy be obliged, on the basis of economic analysis, to check, evaluate and improve the plans drawn up by the enterprises themselves, without, however, altering the scales of profitability which serve as the basis for awarding incentive bonuses to the enterprises.
(Note : These last two categories of proposals aim, on the one hand, at working out a differential system of profitability, on the national scale, taking into account the situations of the different enterprises or groups of enterprises, and, on the other, at not awarding bonuses to enterprises unless they achieve both their norm of profitability and the targets of their plan, targets revised on an objective basis by the Sovnarkhozy.)
(5) That methods of using the bonus funds supplied by the profits of an enterprise be laid down in such a way as to expand the rights of the enterprises to use these funds for purposes of individual and group incentive.
(Note : This no longer relates, therefore, to the methods of awarding bonuses but to the methods of using them. It is at this level that "material interest" really makes itself felt, whereas up to this point what has been involved is rather the indices that make it possible to "measure the efficiency" of the management.)
(6) That the principle be established that the prices of new goods be fixed in a flexible way, so that the most profitable products may be profitable both for the producers and for the consumers, that is, may be profitable on the scale of the economy as a whole.[43]
(Note : The last proposal aims at helping technical progress to make its way by favouring, as regards profitability, the enterprises that are manufacturing new products, which are more advantageous for the national economy. It is indeed obvious that if the profitability of new products remains the same as that of old-established products, while the management of enterprises is evaluated, and bonuses awarded on the basis of profitability, then enterprises will usually have no interest in introducing new products because at first the launching of a new product can give rise to many difficulties and cause a temporary fall in profitability.)
c) Some contradictions or weaknesses in the present practice
of business accounting and planning at enterprise level.
1) Investments without security
Present-day Soviet practice includes the granting without security to each
Whereas, indeed, each enterprise has to buy the raw materials and intermediate products it needs, and, as a result, its purchases enter into its costs of production (which must, at least in principle, encourage it to avoid any waste of intermediate products), it receives its investment funds, so to speak, "free of charge".[44] This may result (and often has resulted) in encouraging the enterprise to ask for investment funds larger than it really needs. It may, in particular, be led to do this in order to build up future "reserves" of increase in production or reduction in cost of production.
Under these conditions, investment is not subject to the same rules of business accounting as current management, something which does not tend to ensure that, at the level of each enterprise, the investment funds are used in the most satisfactory way.
The control exercised over each economic subject by the higher social authorities should, of course, in principle avoid the wasting of investment funds.
To the extent, however, that there is lack of conformity between the rules determining the operation of the economic subject, at the level of the use of current resources, and those which determine its operation at the level of the use of investment funds, and that only the former correspond to its quality as an economic subject, whereas the latter treat it as a mere technical department, distortion and waste seem to be more or less inevitable.
For this reason it is being more and more frequently proposed, in the Soviet Union and in other socialist countries, that the principle of gratuitous granting of investment funds to enterprises be abandoned, as contrary to the principles of autonomous management. If this proposal were adopted, it would mean that the enterprise would have to repay the investment funds granted to it, and perhaps also (this is, at any rate, one of Academician Nemchinov's proposals) would have to pay to the state treasury a certain sum representing a definite percentage of the value of the investment funds tied up in it. This payment would enter into the costs of production of the given enterprise. The justification of this proceeding would be that the present concept of cost (that is, of costs of production without any "capital" charge) is a "category" of simple reproduction, since it includes only current expenses, depreciation and a small "profit". According to Academician Nemchinov (E.G., in Russian, 27th April 1963), each enterprise should be able to re-create, on an expanded scale, its own conditions of work, thanks to a sufficient degree of "profitability" of its investments.
page 103
This presents important problems of business accounting at enterprise level, problems which will have to be discussed in another context.
2) The annual character of the plans
Discussions now going on in the socialist countries show that this constitutes a serious restraint on the introduction of innovations in the enterprises. It is now proposed that this restraint be removed by bringing in ways of estimating the quality of management which will not be confined to the one-year-at-a-time framework.
It may be that advantages that are unreal are ascribed to this kind of "flexibility" in relations between enterprises. On the one hand, it may not be that the using enterprise will always prove able to spot in good time the inadequate quality of the goods supplied to it, and, on the other, in a situation in which every enterprise is working at full capacity, it is not easy for a using enterprise to find a new supplier.[45]
Actually, it would probably be preferable to entrust a social authority with the task of checking the quality of products, by laying down qualitative standards which, if not respected, would result in certain products, though
page 104
supplied in the material sense, having no economic value, or only reduced value. (This raises the problem of a system of price-fixing which would take account of the social usefulness of products -- a problem which deserves treatment on its own.)
d) Methods used by the planning organs to lay down production-
targets
and technical subjects, making use of technical coefficients and tables of inter-sectoral relations.
(3) Finally, in a certain number of cases the forecasts of the planning organs can be worked out on the basis of detailed statistical soundings (polls ) carried out among a certain number of economic subjects or social groups or even individual consumers. Investigations by means of well-chosen samples often bring in information of much greater significance than long questionnaires circulated among thousands of production-units, who complete them with varying degrees of adequacy.
e) Method of carrying out the plans
From the theoretical standpoint what is important to stress is that, on the plane of the methods of carrying out the plans, account has to be taken of the fact that the existence of economic subjects, endowed with relative autonomy, implies the superimposing of macro-decisions taken at the level of the central authorities, upon economic micro-decisions taken at the level of the economic subjects.
To the extent that the micro-decisions taken by an economic subject affect another economic subject, they cannot by their very nature be realised by means of orders,[46]so that an important role has inevitably to be played by contracts concluded between the economic subjects.
page 106
Here again we may quote from the article by Oskar Lange previously mentioned, where he writes:
I must add, too, that contractual ties between economic subjects cannot be as flexible as they need to be unless an adequate number of trading organs are set up within the stated sector, with responsibility for managing stocks of intermediate products and finished products.
Indeed, if each economic subject is to decide the moment at which it will proceed to purchase certain products, and also the specifications of these products, it is essential, to ensure the continuity of the production-process, that there be adequate social stocks of the various categories of product. On the other hand, it is equally essential for correct use of social accumulation that the available stocks should not exceed the real needs. This brings up the problem of the correct management of stocks. It is very important to solve this problem: it conditions, to a large extent, the efficient current functioning of the economic system as a whole.
In the socialist countries they have made attempts to solve the problem of stock management by laying down "norms" for stocks. These norms are made obligatory for the enterprises, which must neither exceed certain quantities nor allow their stocks to fall below a certain minimum level.
In fact, the fixing of these norms usually lacks flexibility. It is seldom possible to determine in this way the volume of stocks that genuine economic subjects may need (the situation is different where what are involved are technical departments functioning within an economic subject).
Optimum management of social stocks is a specific economic problem, the solution of which requires exact calculations and the employment of methods of programming. In order to carry out such tasks there will frequently be need for co-operation by either a trading department within a complex economic subject or else a state trading organ responsible for managing particular products.
Though there is no time to go thoroughly into the problem, it is useful to stress that the way stocks are managed has an impact on the pace at which production plans are accomplished. Here arise a number of problems connected with what can be called the "programming of the carrying-out of the
page 107
plan", problems which cannot be examined immediately because this would take us too far away from the centre of our present concerns.
Whereas, for example, the Soviet state is the owner of certain enterprises, these may themselves be, in a sense, "owners" of their means of production and their products, in so far as they enjoy at one and the same time certain juridical powers and effective capacities to dispose of things which conform to these powers. In this way, the "oneness" of a right of ownership which is characteristic of a certain phase of capitalist development is finally broken up.[48]
The scope of the "right of disposal" possessed by the state enterprises is, of course, strictly limited by the fact that these enterprises themselves belong to the state and that the latter allows them rights over the means of production it assigns to them only to the extent that these rights are used for realising the plan and are necessary for doing this under good conditions of social efficiency.
Here we find again, on the plane of juridical categories, a conclusion to which we had come on the plane of economic categories: the existence of commodity categories inside the state sector of the socialist economy is not merely an "accounting device" or a convenience for calculations. The existence of these categories expresses, simultaneously:
(1) The survival, to a certain degree and within certain limits, of ex-
page 110
changes which take place on the basis of economic decisions taken in a relatively autonomous way by working groups (the autonomy of these groups is relative, because they enjoy it only so as to be able to contribute more effectively to the fulfilment of the targets of the plan), and
(2) The existence, required by this relative autonomy itself, of powers of disposal and rights of usage, powers to alienate and acquire, which have been accorded to the economic subjects, rights which can constitute subordinate forms of property.
If this analysis is accepted, then one is led to consider likewise that money plays, within the state sector of the socialist economy, not merely the role of a unit of account but also a real economic role. And this role is, to make it possible, to a certain extent, for the different economic subjects to get rid of their products, or to provide themselves with products, on the basis of their own initiatives.
If the plan could foresee the exact quantities of products that each working group would provide, and of those that would be required by each group, and if it were in a position to ensure at the desired moment the full satisfaction of the needs of each group, it would also be able to decide where the products should come from to meet each group's needs and the direction in which the goods provided by each group should be sent. Under these conditions, the products could be dealt with by means of socially efficient allotment orders, and there would be no further need either for purchases or for sales; nor, therefore, for money.
On the other hand, since such forecasting and such a balance, a priori, between supplies and needs are not yet possible (with a few exceptions), and, especially, since they cannot be effected with sufficient precision (from the standpoint of the time and place at which supplies must be produced and despatched), it is necessary to allow a sufficient margin of initiative to a certain number of working groups; this is what, basically, makes it necessary to use money for buying and selling.[49]
In the socialist economy of today, money thus plays not merely an accounting role but also a real one (on the economic and juridical plane). There are, for this reason, in the planned economies of today, side by side, a material plan and a financial plan. Only with the disappearance of the commodity categories within the state sector of the socialist economy will it be possible for the financial plan to disappear also, giving place to material planning alone (which will also, of course, include planning and accounting of labour expenditure ).
|
|
The following abbreviations have been used: V.E. = Voprosy Ekonomiki, S.W. = Sowjetwissenschaft, E.P. = Economic Problems of Socialism in the USSR, E.G. = Ekonomicheskaya Gazeta, S.N.Kh. = Soviet Narodnogo Khozyaistva (Sovnarkhoz, or Council of National Economy).
[p. 31]
2
In a note written in the margin of Bukharin's book Lenin remarks that the definition the author gives of political economy (the science of a social economy based on production of commodities, i.e., science of an unorganised social economy) makes us take "a step back as compared with Engels", who, as we know, defined political economy in the broad sense as the "science of the conditions and forms under which the various human societies have produced and exchanged and, on this basis, have distributed their products".
For our subject, this aspect of the discussion to which Bukharin's book gave rise is obviously of great importance. The views expressed by Lenin about this book were not all, incidentally, so negative as certain commentators were to allege some years later. Some of Lenin's comments will be found in Zamechaniya na Knigu N. Bukharina "Ekonomika Perekhodnogo Perioda ", 2nd edn., Moscow, 1932 (see also Vol. XI of the 1928 edn. of Lenin's works).
A commentary on this discussion and its continuations (which therefore gives many other references) will be found in A. Kaufman, "The origin of the Political Economy of Socialism", in Soviet Studies, January 1953, pp. 243 et seq. See also Ronald L. Meek, Studies in the Labour Theory of Value, London, 1956, especially pp. 256-67.
[p. 31]
3
While the idea that commodity categories were destined to disappear in the first phase of socialist society was generally accepted by Marxists before the October Revolution, we know that Lenin was one of the first to renounce this conception and stress the importance of economic calculation even at the level of production-units (cf., particularly, his "Report to the 9th All-Russia Congress of Soviets, December 1921", Collected Works, Russian 4th edn., Vol. 33, pp. 160-1).
[p. 33]
4
This is exactly what I do accept.
[p. 33]
5
Quotations taken from Lenin's article "On Co-operation" (1923).
[p. 36]
6
Le Capital, Costes edn., Vol. I, p. 65. (Eng. edn. of 1938, pp. 50-1.) The German reads "selbst bewusst ".
[p. 41]
7
Doubtless because they could not be, without reference to social praxis.
[p. 42]
8
The superimposing of collective or communal ownership over individual (family) or personal production can be observed, of course, in a number of economic systems in course of transition, e.g., when primitive communal forms are evolving into exploitation by separate families.
[p. 46]
page 112
9 960 in March 1962, about 1,500 after November 1962.
[p. 46]
10
These figures refer to different years in the decade 1950-60. They are quoted from the article by L. Berri and Y. Shvikov entitled: "A comparison between production-structures in the USSR and in other countries (on the basis of inter-sectoral balances)", in V.E., 1963, No. 1, trans. in S.W., 1963, No. 8, pp. 818 et seq.; figures taken from p. 826.
[p. 49]
11
The expression "production-relations" is used here in the general sense in which Marx used it when he considered "the distribution of the members of society among the various kinds of production" as "the subjection of individuals to certain relations of production" (cf. Marx, Contribution d la Critique de l'Economie Politique (Contribution to the Critique of Political Economy), Giard edn., 1928, p.327: American and Indian edns., p. 286).
[p. 55]
12
An account (in French) of the conditions governing the conclusion and execution of contracts in Bulgaria, at the level of the socialist trading organisations, will be found in the article by Dr. Ivan Vlahov (Sofia): "Le système des contrats des organisations commerciales socialistes", in Bulletin du Centre National pour l'étude des Etats de l'Est, 1963, No. 3 (Brussels), pp.229 et seq.:
[p. 56]
13
Dr. Vlahov, in the article already mentioned, calls this "transport in transit". Describing the similar role assumed by the wholesale trading enterprises of the socialist sector as intermediaries between the producers and the retailers, he writes: "In the contractual relations between the producing enterprises and the trading ones, a big part is played by transport in transit, as it is not necessary actually to deliver the goods to the depots of the wholesale trading organisations. The latter present the producing enterprises with lists showing how the goods are to be allotted, stating quantities, varieties and delivery dates for each receiver, and the minimum norms for transport in transit." (Op. cit., p. 238.)
[p. 58]
14
The first instance implies a temporary degeneration of some of the functions of money, while the second shows that the social use of money has been transcended, that is, it has begun to wither away.
[p. 60]
15
The significance of this circulation of currency tokens becomes apparent, over and above the field we are studying at the moment, when the economic authority which has received these tokens is able to use them as money, that is, to undertake purchases which do not strictly result from decisions taken at a different level.
[p. 62]
16
On the Soviet trusts and the Glavki, see my book L'Economie Soviétique (Paris, 1950, pp. 122 and 126).
[p. 64]
17
This type of organisation corresponds to some extent to the "Sbyta " and "Prombazy " of the USSR (cf. op cit., pp. 230-2).
[p. 64]
18
This type of integration is being effected at present in the USSR, at the regional level, through the formation of "Soviet firms" embracing a certain number of enterprises of the same type, the most important of which takes on the leadership of the whole group. Generally speaking, the constitution of such a "firm" is submitted for approval by the Sovnarkhoz to which the enterprises are subject. The integration thus achieved is more complete
in some cases than in others. It may even lead to the birth of a new economic and juridical subject, taking the place of the separate enterprises which previously existed. The "firm" so constituted may, finally, take on the functions that were formerly the responsibility of a Branch Department of the Sovnarkhoz. When this happens, an economico-technical hierarchy has replaced an administrative one. On the "Soviet firms", see V. Kamenetsky's article "The Soviet firms, results and prospects", in V.E., 1964, No. 5, p. 62.
[p. 64]
19
Within the capitalist economy this line is marked by the merging of enterprises, with the appearance of buying and selling agencies and management centres. However, capitalist ownership and the contradictory interests of the private owners continually set limits to evolution in this direction, or else, when it does take place, this happens for the exclusive advantage of one particularly powerful financial group, and not necessarily on an economically efficient scale.
[p. 65]
20
From the standpoint of the relations that a production-unit enjoys with the "rest" of the economy (relations which, on the basis of state ownership, are of decisive importance for the retention or disappearance of the commodity categories) the fact that a production-unit disposes of all its products to one single central sales office may, provided that this organisation is not artificial, have consequences that come very close to the integration of one production-unit into another.
[p. 65]
21
The break-up of such organic wholes which took place in Cuba immediately after the Revolution was one of the factors in the fall in sugar production. Since 1963 there has been a move to re-establish organisational unity through a National Sugar Commission and regional and local commissions.
[p. 67]
22
In Romania such agro-industrial combines now exist, integrating into a complex economic unit cultivation, stockraising, tinning-plant, factories making animal foodstuffs, and even shops for distributing the products.
[p. 67]
23
See note 17.
[p. 67]
24
A problem which, though important, I cannot deal with for the moment, is that of the limits set to the integration of activities in a particular productive economic complex. A quick observation that can be made, however, is that economic integration takes place only in so far as all the activities integrated satisfy a single economic and technical function and complement each other. In other words, the limit to economic integration is determined by the specific nature of the functions to be carried out, and the relevant test is the cost incurred by a particular activity. It is therefore necessary to know whether or not an integrated function is carried out at a lower cost than a non-integrated one. The idea of economic integration leads on to the idea of the "master of the operation": this role is played, in an integrated economic group, by the essential functional link in this group, i.e., the activity to which all the others are subordinate.
The integration of a certain number of activities in an economic complex makes the latter collectively responsible, within a socialist economy, for the
fulfilment of a group of tasks. What the plan lays down are the tasks of this complex and the general external conditions for their accomplishment, while the internal conditions are the business of the management of the complex; this management may be carried out through a functional hierarchy of responsibilities.
[p. 68]
25
This is not enough to situate this company among the very largest American companies from the standpoint of turnover and numbers employed. Thus, General Motors' turnover in 1963 was $16,500,000,000 and in that year it employed 640,000 people and invested $647,000,000 in plant. The net value of the firm's plant on 31 December 1963 was estimated at $3,000,000,000 and its net working capital at $3,700,000,000.
[p. 68]
26
It must be stressed that private property relations often hinder the appearance of an economic subject when the productive forces are ready for it. This is particularly noticeable in the capitalist setting, where the limits of enterprises are determined by property-relations, so that enterprises belonging to different owners (joint-stock companies, for instance), but which potentially form a single economic subject, continue to function independently of each other. "Mergers" between enterprises sometimes put an end to this type of situation. The presence of the same directors on the boards of different companies which form together a potential single economic subject may also constitute an attempt to overcome the difficulties resulting from the obstacles put by private property in the way of the appearance of an economic subject (this cross-membership, these "personal links", may also, of course, be due to reasons quite other than those mentioned here).
In other cases, nationalisation, within the framework of capitalism, may be the only way of overcoming the obstacles caused by private property and preventing the formation of a single economic subject, though the latter is objectively necessary; in the case of the French economy, the formation of the S.N.C.F. (state railways), E.D.F. (state electricity), Gaz de France (state gas) and Houillères de France (state coal-mines) apparently reflects a situation like this.
Under socialism, too, juridical rules may for a time obstruct the appearance of an economic subject. This happened in the Soviet Union, when factories that ought to have been operating in an integrated way, e.g., within a framework of organic co-operation, were dependent on different central ministries which opposed such co-operation. This is what has been called the problem of "administrative compartmentalisation". It must be added that the reorganisation on territorial lines undertaken with the establishment of the Sovnarkhozy has given rise to a certain number of cases of "regional compartmentalisation".
[p. 72]
27
It should be observed in passing that this requirement implies that, for a given level of economic interdependence it is not possible usefully to go below a certain level of decentralisation. This is connected with the impossibility of "condensing" all the information needed for socially useful decisions in a system of prices such that all the micro-economic decisions
taken always coincide with the macro-economic ones. This is the other side of the fact that the consequences of certain decisions depend strictly on other decisions which have to be taken simultaneously (the complementary character of certain decisions). This is a complex problem to which I shall come back when I discuss the role of prices in a planned economy.
[p. 75]
28
Cf. V.E., February 1962, pp. 114 et seq.
[p. 77]
29
In his book called Sovkhoz, Kolkhoz ou le problématique du communisme, Paris, Editions du Seuil, 1964, René Dumont, who declares in favour of the organising within the collective farms of small, individualised work-brigades, endowed with permanent means of production and financial autonomy, writes on this subject:
page 116
drawing up of internal plans for the workshops and departments in question.
The perfecting of the practical forms in which internal economic calculation can be carried out is an extremely complex matter. This is clearly to be seen when we analyse the discussions which have taken place on this subject in the Soviet Union. Thus, in the manual entitled Ekonomika sotsialisticheskikh promyshlennikh predpriyatii (Moscow, 1956), we read:
page 117
aeroplanes which will then be moving regularly across the West-European sky, and of fixing the locations of the relevant ground installations, together with the procedures for ensuring take-off and landing by this air-fleet. The simulator will make it possible to trace the effects of the various possible combinations of ground-installations and the relations between these and the aircraft in flight. A simulator capable of doing this necessitates an electronic brain equipped with over 100,000 transistors.
[p. 80]
33
The problem of the organs responsible for this co-ordination will be dealt with a little later.
[p. 81]
34
It is clear that bureaucratic distortion of the economy can also occur when, inside a complex economic subject, the responsibility for taking certain decisions is entrusted to economic authorities which are uselessly high up in the hierarchy and less well placed than authorities lower down for taking completely effective decisions.
Contrariwise, if the responsibility for taking decisions is entrusted to authorities which are not sufficiently high up the ladder to be able to take account of all the necessary information, together with the complementary nature of certain decisions (cf. note 27), a certain "economic dislocation" will result.
Economic dislocation and bureaucratisation of the economy alike result in a loss of efficiency (in comparison with what could be achieved under other conditions), i.e., in poor co-ordination between decisions, or poor adaptation of means to ends.
[p. 82]
35
A point here which is essential and which must never be lost sight of seems to me that, within the framework of a planned economy, every economico-juridical subject in the production sphere is merely a link in the division of labour, and a link destined to be subordinated to an increasing extent to a larger subject (in proportion as the socialisation of the productive forces progresses) of which it thus tends to become, little by little, a mere technical department.
This being so, the setting-up of elected decision-making organs at the level of each production-unit can, as a rule, only be a measure that holds back the complete socialisation of the means of production and even sets an obstacle in its way, emptying of its content the public ownership of these means of production and replacing it, de facto, with ownership by a limited group of workers. When this occurs, we are not on the road to the building of socialism but on the road to the degeneration of the very conditions essential for social planning.
It must further be stressed that when the aim of production is no longer profit but consumption, the social control of productive activity which is essential would seem to need to be exercised more and more at the level of consumption, i.e., of the evaluation of social needs. This being so, proposals aimed at setting up a form of control wielded mainly by the producers as such can only hold back the adapting of production to its final aim, namely, social needs.
This does not, of course, rule out control by producers over the conditions
must be said that the control that the producers should exercise over these production-units is a control that belongs to the producers as a whole and not merely the narrow groups of workers who produce within each of these production-units considered in isolation. This control by all the producers over all the production-units of the state sector raises the problem of political democracy, and so of the democratic structure of the state. This is quite a different problem from that of the internal organisation of the different production-units, and we should be going too far beyond our present task if we were to try to study it here.
In any case, democratic functioning of the state and of the ruling party constitutes the condition for genuine socialist planning which must subordinate both the aims of the plan and the means of achieving it to the overall interests of the workers and of society.
[p. 94]
36
Naturally, a thorough knowledge of these characteristics and the potentialities inherent in them is only possible given close consultation with the members of these groups and stimulation of their initiative. Thus L. M. Gatovsky, summing up the work of a seminar devoted to "Cybernetics and Planning" (cf. V.E., 1964, No. 6) is justified in stressing that "no centralised optimisation of the plan and no automisation of management detracts from the importance of local initiative . . ." (p. 95).
[p. 95]
37
As in the system of planning at two levels proposed by Kornai and Liptak.
[p. 95]
38
Cf. J. Vernes, "Plans, bénéfices et primes en URSS" (Plans, profits and bonuses in the USSR), Economie et Politique, December 1963, pp. 48 et seq.
[p. 95]
39
Of course, as a result of advances in the productive forces themselves and also of the use of electronic methods of calculation, there are grounds for supposing that these difficulties will be overcome in the not too distant future, at least so far as certain branches of activity in the more highly industrialised socialist countries are concerned, but this means that when that time comes, the character of "economic subject" attaching to the production-units functioning in those branches of activity will already be on the way out.
[p. 98]
40
Oskar Lange, "How do I visualise the Polish economic model?" (in German), in Polen von Heute, 1st February 1957.
[p. 100]
41
Though these problems have been for several years the subject of special attention in the Soviet Union, they are far from having been solved. Thus, when, at a meeting of the Council of National Economy of the USSR in spring of 1964, the activities of the Sovnarkhozy of the Kharkov and Central Volga areas were examined, it was noted that, though the industrial enterprises of these areas had surpassed, in overall terms, their production plans and other targets laid down in the form of technico-economic indicators (norms of consumption of intermediate products, productivity, etc.), more than 40 per cent of them had failed to fulfil their tasks as regards the particular goods produced, and thereby "the national economy has failed to obtain large quantities of electrical machines, superchargers, goods trucks, spare parts and mining equipment" (cf. V.E., 1964, No. 6, p. 94).
[p. 100]
page 120
42
Cf. the article by J. Vernes (see note 38).
[p. 100]
43
These were Liberman's proposals put forward in Pravda of 9 September 1962.
[p. 101]
44
It is only through "depreciation norms" (which are usually low) that the immobilisation of investment funds by an enterprise may lead to a certain increase in its costs of production.
[p. 102]
45
The objection that to authorise this practice would upset the plan forecast is, in the main, of formal validity only, since it is failure to respect qualitative standards (even if this be not measured) that really upsets the plan forecasts.
[p. 103]
46
Of course, micro-decisions which affect only one economic subject by itself can take the form of orders emanating from the management of this subject, or from the organ which manages part of this subject, and addressed to a working group or even to a particular worker, but these are orders that concern the internal functioning of the subject and are thus of a technical nature.
[p. 105]
47
Article in Polen von Heute referred to in note 40, p. 11.
[p. 106]
48
It will be observed that, with the development of joint-stock companies, as well as other factors, this "oneness" is already tending to break up: the shareholders are the joint owners of the joint-stock company in which they have invested their capital, but the company is the "owner" of its means of production. The general meeting of the shareholders having, in principle, defined the purpose of the company's activity, it is under the responsibility of the managing director, who is not necessarily a shareholder, that the means of production are put to current use and that some of them may even be bought or sold (in so far as these purchases and sales do not alter the purpose of the company's activity). More important economic decisions (extension of activity, new investments, etc.) are taken by the board of directors, whereas the shareholders' general meeting theoretically takes the decisions with a larger bearing; actually, these decisions are more often than not prepared by the permanent staff of the management under conditions such that the general meeting can do nothing but rubber-stamp them.
This brings out how, in this instance, there is a lack of conformity between the juridical power and the effective capacity of the shareholders' general meeting. What has happened is that the social character of the productive forces has burst some of the limitations imposed by the private ownership of these forces, though this takes place to the advantage not of society as a whole but to that of a small number of especially powerful shareholders.
[p. 109]
49
If the impossibility of an exact forecast were confined to the sphere of individual consumption, it would only be in this sphere that the commodity categories had a role to play; so it is not impossible that the commodity categories may cease to exist in the production sphere while continuing to some extent in that of consumption. It is not out of the question, however, that commodity categories may, on the contrary, disappear first in the consumption sphere and only later in that of production. These are problems that, for the time being, can only be mentioned in passing.
[p. 110]